Tuesday, September 23, 2014

Russian view of airstrikes in Syria

Russia's view is that airstrikes in Syria should not take place without the consent of the government of Syria.  From RT, the official Russian news outlet:

RT

Updated 01:19 a.m. Moscow time.
MOSCOW, September 23 (RIA Novosti) - Russian President Vladimir Putin, in a phone conversation with UN Secretary General Ban Ki-moon, said that airstrikes against the Islamic State (IS) targets in Syria should not be conducted without consent of Syrian government, the Kremlin said on Tuesday.
"Vladimir Putin and Ban Ki-moon have exchanged opinions on efforts of the international community joined against the 'Islamic State' group. Russian side emphasized, that airstrikes against the Islamic State terrorists' bases, located on the territory of Syria, should not be conducted without the consent of Syrian government," the Kremlin press service said in a statement.
The IS, also known as the Islamic State of Iraq and Greater Syria (ISIS) or the Islamic State of Iraq and the Levant (ISIL), has been fighting against Syrian government since 2012. In June 2014, the group extended its attacks to northern and western Iraq, declaring a caliphate on the territories over which it had control.
Earlier in September, US President Barack Obama has announced the formation of an international coalition to fight the IS militants and authorized US airstrikes against IS targets in Syria, while continuing airstrikes in Iraq, which the United States began in August.
Note that Russia has a naval base at Tartus, near where the bombing is taking place.  The naval facility is Russia's only direct naval access to the Atlantic, and the Syrian government i an ally of Russia's.

Still, it is curious that Russia has not persuaded Syri to permit it to bomb ISIS.  Russia is no friend to Arab jihadists.




Friday, September 12, 2014

We become what we most fear.

We become what we most fear.

Hatred never ceases by hatred,but by love alone is healed;This is a great and eternal law.


Durell
  • Israeli intelligence veterans refuse to serve in Palestinian territories
Innocent people under military rule exposed to surveillance by Israel, say 43 ex-members of Unit 8200, including reservists
  • Peter Beaumont in Jerusalem
  • The Guardian, Friday 12 September 2014 05.44 EDTThree Israeli intelligence veterans talk about their experience in the Palestinian territories
Forty-three veterans of one of Israel’s most secretive military intelligence units – many of them still active reservists – have signed a public letter refusing to serve in operations involving the occupied Palestinian territories because of the widespread surveillance of innocent residents.
The signatories include officers, former instructors and senior NCOs from the country’s equivalent of America’s NSA or Britain’s GCHQ, known as Unit 8200 – or in Hebrew as Yehida Shmoneh-Matayim.
They allege that the “all-encompassing” intelligence the unit gathers on Palestinians – much of it concerning innocent people – is used for “political persecution” and to create divisions in Palestinian society.
The largest intelligence unit in the Israeli military, Unit 8200 intercepts electronic communications including email, phone calls and social media in addition to targeting military and diplomatic traffic.
The signatories say, however, that a large part of their work was unrelated to Israel’s security or defence, but appeared designed to perpetuate the occupation by “infiltrating” and “controlling” all aspects of Palestinian life.
Written in uncompromising language the letter states: “We, veterans of Unit 8200, reserve soldiers both past and present, declare that we refuse to take part in actions against Palestinians and refuse to continue serving as tools in deepening the military control over the Occupied Territories.”
They add: “The Palestinian population under military rule is completely exposed to espionage and surveillance by Israeli intelligence. It is used for political persecution and to create divisions within Palestinian society by recruiting collaborators and driving parts of Palestinian society against itself. In many cases, intelligence prevents defendants from receiving a fair trial in military courts, as the evidence against them is not revealed.”
Accompanying the letter – published in the Israeli media on Friday, and organised several months before the recent Gaza war – are a series of testimonies provided by the signatories to Yedioth Ahronoth and shared with the Guardian.
A common complaint, made in both the testimonies and in interviews given by some of the signatories, including to the Guardian this week, is that some of the activities the soldiers were asked to engage in had more in common with the intelligence services of oppressive regimes than of a democracy.
Among allegations made in the statements are that:
• A significant proportion of the unit’s Palestinian objectives “are innocent people unconnected to any military activity. They interest the unit for other reasons, usually without having the slightest idea that they’re intelligence targets.” According to the testimonies those targets were not treated any differently from terrorists.
• Personnel were instructed to keep any damaging details of Palestinians’ lives they came across, including information on sexual preferences, infidelities, financial problems or family illnesses that could be “used to extort/blackmail the person and turn them into a collaborator”.
• Former members claim some intelligence gathered by the unit was not collected in the service of the Israeli state but in pursuit of the “agendas” of individual Israeli politicians. In one incident, for which no details have been provided, one signatory recalls: “Regarding one project in particular, many of us were shocked as we were exposed to it. Clearly it was not something we as soldiers were supposed to do. The information was almost directly transferred to political players and not to other sections of the security system.”
• Unit members swapped intercepts they gathered involving “sex talk” for their own entertainment.
The letter has been sent to the chief of staff of Israel’s armed forces and also the head of military intelligence.
Unit 8200 is one of the most prestigious in the Israeli public’s mind, with many who serve in it going on to high-flying jobs after their military service, many in Israel’s hi-tech sector.
According to an article this year in Haaretz, former unit members include a supreme court justice, the director general of the finance ministry, an internationally successful author, the chief executive of one of Israel’s largest accountancy firms and the economy ministry’s chief scientist.
Operating a signals interception base, the unit is also at the front of Israel’s cyberwar capabilities. According to some reports – never confirmed – it was involved in developing the Stuxnet virus used to attack Iran’s nuclear programme.
Most of those who signed the letter have served in the unit in the last decade – as recently as three years ago in full-time military service – with the majority still on the active reserve list, meaning they can be called up at any time.
All of those who spoke to the Guardian said they were “highly motivated” to join the unit and had volunteered to serve extra time in it beyond their national service.
Although there have been “refusenik” letters before – most famously more than a decade ago when a group of reserve pilots refused to participate in targeted assassinations – such detailed complaints from within Israel’s intelligence services are highly unusual.
Three of those involved, two sergeants and a captain who gave interviews to the Guardian and a handful of other foreign media before the letter was released this week, were at pains to make clear they were not interested in disclosing state secrets. They had engaged a high-profile lawyer to avoid breaking Israeli law – including by identifying themselves in public. Copies of the letter sent to their unit commander, however, use their full names.
Those involved told the Guardian they were proud of some of the work they had done, which they believed had contributed to Israel’s security.
In their interviews, they described a culture of impunity where soldiers were actively discouraged in training lessons from questioning the legality of orders, and of being deliberately misled by commanders about the circumstances of a case in which one member of their unit refused to cooperate in the bombing of a building with civilians in it in retaliation for an attack in Israel.
They added that there were in effect “no rules” governing which Palestinians could be targeted and that the only restraint on their intelligence gathering in the occupied territories was “resources”.
“In intelligence – in Israel intelligence regarding Palestinians – they don’t really have rights,” said Nadav, 26, a sergeant, who is now a philosophy and literature student in Tel Aviv. “Nobody asks that question. It’s not [like] Israeli citizens, where if you want to gather information about them you need to go to court.”
He said: “The intelligence gathering about Palestinians is not clean. When you rule a population that does not have political rights, laws like we have, [then] the nature of this regime of ruling over people, especially when you do it for many years, [is that] it forces you to take control or infiltrate every aspect of their life.”
“D”, a 29-year-old captain who served for eight years, added: “[That] question is one of the messages that we feel it is very important to get across mostly to the Israeli public.
“That is a very common misconception about intelligence … when we were enlisting in the military [we thought] our job is going to be minimising violence, minimising loss of lives, and that made the moral side of it feel much easier.”
He added: “What the IDF does in the occupied territories is rule another people. One of the things you need to do is defend yourself from them, but you also need to oppress the population.
“You need to weaken the politics. You need to strengthen and deepen your control of Palestinian society so that the [Israeli] state can remain [there] in the long term. We can’t talk about specifics … [but] intelligence is used to apply pressure to people to make them cooperate with Israel.
“It’s important to say, the reason I decided to refuse – and I decided to refuse long before the recent [Gaza] operation. It was when I realised that what I was doing was the same job that the intelligence services of every undemocratic regime are doing.
“This realisation was what made me [realise] personally that I’m part of this large mechanism that is trying to defend or perpetuate its presence in the occupied territories.”
The last major refusenik episode in Israel to grab the public’s attention was in 2002 when 27 reserve pilots published a letter refusing to fly assassination sorties over Gaza after 14 civilians, including children, were killed alongside Salah Shehade, the leader of Hamas’s military wing, in a bombing.
Nadav made a reference to the killing – and the outcry that surrounded it. “When you look at what happened this summer, when building after building were destroyed and the inhabitants and hundreds of innocent people were killed and no one raised an eyebrow, as opposed to just one decade ago when the killing of a family of a commander of Hamas shocked people. It was a huge story in Israel.”
Replying to the refusenik letter and the allegations, a spokesman for the Israel Defence Forces criticised the soldiers for making their complaints public, and attempted to cast doubt on the claims.
“The intelligence corps has no record that the specific violations in the letter ever took place. Immediately turning to the press instead of to their officers or relevant authorities is suspicious and raises doubts as to the seriousness of the claims.

“Regarding claims of harm caused to civilians, the IDF maintains a rigorous process which takes into account civilian presence before authorising strikes against targets.”

_________________

Fearful Israelis

  



Desperate Palestinians





Thursday, September 11, 2014

Iran fights ISIS to protect a pipeline in Iraq.


Is Iran a member of the ISIS Coalition the US has put together?  If not, why not (domestic politics aside)?

The pipeline mentioned in the article below, as planned, would run from the South Pars gas field through Iran, Iraq, Syria, and Lebanon, countries not aligned with the US.
   
Iran already has an outlet in the Persian Gulf at Assaluyeh, across from the South Pars field, the largest natural gas field in the world. The Fifth Fleet, stationed in Bhrain in the Gulf, hindersIranian  shipment through the Gulf.  Presumably shipment through Syria would escape US sanctions.

________


Assaluyeh and South Pars:




he proposed Iran, Iraq, Syria pipeline


For a discussion of possible routes for the pipeline, see here.

The Epoch Times - Breaking news, independent China news

Fighting in Iraq Delays Iran Gas Exports

⋅ September 11, 2014
TEHRAN, Iran—The fighting between Iraqi troops and Islamic State militants will delay even further the planned start of Iranian natural gas exports to neighboring Iraq, Iran’s oil minister was quoted as saying Wednesday.

Oil Minister Bijan Zanganeh said the pipeline, which is still under construction on the Iraqi side, goes partly through territory now controlled by the Islamic State group.

The extremist group carried out a blitz this summer, seizing much of Iraq’s north and west and is now battling with Iraqi forces, backed by U.S. airstrikes, who are trying to take back lost ground.

Pipeline workers, mainly Iranians, have come under attack several times, especially in Iraq’s Diyala province, which has disrupted work, he said.



P.s.  From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia  The Epoch Times originally targeted Chinese readers living abroad and reported on various abuses and inner workings of the Communist Party of China (CCP). The paper's reports on China are highly critical of the PRC government, particularly in its tone and commentaries towards the Communist Party. The paper is unique in giving significant attention to Falun Gong's campaigns, particularly their attempt to sue former Chinese President Jiang Zemin under civil legislation for genocide, which many mainstream publications have not covered.[29] As reported by the paper itself, Chinese journalists relayed stories overseas of alleged human rights abuses, infringements on civil liberties and corruption in the CCP, among others.[5]

_________

If the US and Iran reach agreement over the nuclear issue and sanctions on Iran are lifted, the whole world changes, for the better.   The pressure on the US from those who benefit from the status quo is terrific; and Obama has two more years.

Wednesday, July 2, 2014

In geopolitical terms, Russia is winning on its borders, for now; and the Saudi have a black eye


If you want to know about the Saudi official support of SISI, read the article below, from the Economic Times, according to Wikipedia the second-most-read English-language financial journal in the world, after the Wall Street Journal..  It is published in India.

Russia is having a field day.  It wants to support Iran in Syria, what better way than to support the Shia in Iran than by supplying fighter planes to Bagdad., and with no downside to Russia.  At the same time, Russia gets in a poke at the US for the US's support of Ukraine.

Incidentally, SISI is the mortal enemy of Al Qaeda, and both seem to be the mortal enemy of the West.  Whom do you wish us to bomb, Senator Graham?

Iraq crisis: Besides Saudi Arabia, India seeks Russia’s help to secure release of abducted citizens
Dipanjan Roy Chaudhury, ET Bureau 
Jun 28, 2014, 06.58AM IST 

NEW DELHI: India has sought Russia's help to secure the release of its abducted citizens in insurgency-hit Iraq, turning to its trusted old partner even as it is trying to negotiate with the militant group ISIS (Islamic State of Iraq and Syria) that kidnapped the construction workers in Mosul.
The government had discussed the issue with the Russian deputy prime minister Dmitry Rogozin on his visit to Delhi last week, officials said. Simultaneously, the government is heavily relying on Saudi Arabia, which has influence in the region and within ISIS, the officials said, adding that Saudi Arabia has assured India that the kidnapped nationals are safe and receiving ration.  [Emphasis added.]



Thursday, June 26, 2014

Towward a united Kursistan

The Kurds were the only consistent friends of the US during the long Iraq War.  The US owes them something, and that something is oil-rich Kirkuk, which they now occupy.

The Iraqi constitution provides that Kirkuk should belong to whomever wins a plebiscite in that City, and Kurds would surely win.  So the Central Government has refused to hold the plebiscite and has held on to Kirkuk until now.

Many Kurds live in Turkey and Iran.  Many want  the independent nation of Kurdistan promised by the 1920 Treat of Sèvres, at the conclusion of WWI.  Britain and France broke the Treaty  and carved Kurdistan into subordinate three parts.

Kurds have as long  history, as long as any people on earth.  They remember.

Kerry, do the right thing.  Let Turkey and Iran, both with big Kurdish populations, become friends of our friends, the Kurds.

d

From the New York Times

Kerry Implores Kurdish Leader to Join a Government and Not Break Away
By MICHAEL R. GORDONJUNE 24, 2014
ERBIL, Iraq — Secretary of State John Kerry urged the president of Iraq’s Kurdish autonomous region on Tuesday not to seek his own state and instead help form a government in Baghdad.

“I am going to bring up the elephant in the room,” Mr. Kerry told the president, Masoud Barzani, who serves as the leader of the Iraqi Kurds, a minority who have long sought independence. “This moment requires statesmanship.”

Mr. Kerry’s statements, shared by a senior State Department official who attended the meeting, were prompted by recent comments by Mr. Barzani in an interview with CNN about what he called the need for Kurdish self-determination.
Mr. Barzani neither withdrew those comments nor said that he would take concrete steps to pursue self-determination during his meeting with Mr. Kerry, who traveled to Iraq on Monday as part of an emergency effort to help deal with a growing Sunni insurgency threatening to partition the country.

But Mr. Barzani made no secret of his disdain for Prime Minister Nuri Kamal al-Maliki, a Shiite. Mr. Barzani also bluntly expressed his sense that the gains by the Islamic State in Iraq and Syria, the Sunni extremist group known as ISIS, had changed the political landscape.
Photo


Secretary of State John Kerry and Masoud Barzani, the president of Iraq’s Kurdish autonomous region, on Tuesday in Erbil, Iraq. 
Credit
Pool photo by Brendan Smialowski
“We are facing a new reality and a new Iraq,” Mr. Barzani said at the start of his meeting with Mr. Kerry.
Mr. Kerry’s trip to the Kurdish regional capital, Erbil, was his first as secretary of state. He met with Mr. Barzani after meetings in Baghdad on Monday with Mr. Maliki and rival Shiite and Sunni politicians. (The last secretary of state to visit Erbil was Condoleezza Rice, in 2006, at the height of the American-led Iraq occupation.)
After ISIS members took over the northern city of Mosul two weeks ago and began to move south, Kurdish security forces responded by seizing Kirkuk, a city in an oil-rich region that has long been divided between Arabs and Kurds.
The Kurds’ expansion has put them in a position to demand more autonomy in political talks over Iraq’s future. But it might also complicate the effort to cobble together a new Iraqi government, particularly one that does not include Mr. Maliki, long accused of autocratic tendencies by Iraqi politicians.
American officials have made clear privately that they would support the selection of a new prime minister if Mr. Maliki’s rivals would unite behind an alternative. But it is uncertain whether Sunni and Kurdish political parties can find enough common ground in forming a new government now that the Kurdish militia, known as the pesh merga, has taken control of Kirkuk.

“Ousting Maliki will require the cooperation of all the other blocs,” said Ramzy Mardini, an expert on Iraq and a nonresident fellow at the Atlantic Council, an independent research organization based in Washington.

∼∼∼∼∼∼∼∼∼∼

How Kurdistan might look under the Treaty of Sèvres:




US helps China's tarde ambitions,alas!

If you want to know how the US-Israel isolationist policy toward Iran aids China's trade ambitions, read this article.

Perhaps developments in Iraq will bring about a modification of US' draconian policies toward Iran.  Israel will not change until it makes peace with Palestinians.

d

The development of Gwadar Port could provide some relief to the under-developed Balochistan. PHOTO: FILE
Published: June 23, 2014

ISLAMABAD: 
Over the years, there have been much more stress on connecting regional countries through road, rail and pipelines in order to defeat the threat of global economic recession. European countries followed this model by laying a gas pipeline from Russia to meet their energy needs and support the economy despite US pressure. 
In the same way, the US wants to link Asian countries including Central Asia, Afghanistan, Pakistan and India through a gas pipeline and power transmission lines originating from Turkmenistan. This runs contrary to the Gwadar Port plan that will connect Pakistan to regional states in a way that does not suit US and Indian interests. 
Gwadar Port, situated in Balochistan, will create a nexus between Pakistan, Iran, China and Central Asian States that will generate billions of dollars in revenues. 
Earlier, the US played a key role during Pervez Musharraf’s government in handing over the development of Gwadar Port to the Port Authority of Singapore (PAS), denying China a chance to run a warm water, deep-sea port on the Arabian Sea just opposite the Gulf of Oman, an important route for oil tankers going from the Gulf to Japan and western countries. 
The port can serve as a gateway to the Strait of Hormuz and can compete with UAE ports by improving existing links to the Caspian region and providing a better trade route to the landlocked region. 
According to Arthur D Little, the main consulting firm for Gwadar’s development, the port is expected to generate billions of dollars in revenues and create at least two million jobs. 
The handover of port operations to PAS did not only hold back planned multi-billion-dollar investments by China, but PAS also failed to make the port operational, causing a loss of billions of dollars in port and cargo handling charges as well as freight on import and export of goods. 
Later, the control of Gwadar Port was given to China and an agreement was signed with China Overseas Ports Holding Company on May 16, 2013 to transfer operational rights from PAS. 
Energy projects 
After taking over, China decided to revive its investment plan and make massive capital injection into expansion of the port and energy projects. 
Under the Early Harvest Programme, China will pump $50 billion up to 2017 into a host of projects including coal, solar and wind energy units. 
An investment of $35 billion is anticipated in energy schemes, which will generate 23,000 megawatts. Lahore-Karachi Motorway, expansion of Gwadar Port and integrated infrastructure development in Gwadar will bring further investment of $11 billion. 
The development of Gwadar Port could provide some relief to the under-developed Balochistan, where the ranks of unemployed are increasing in the absence of infrastructure development, sparking unrest in the region. 
Balochistan is the first major gas producing province, but despite that it is a deprived region where poverty runs high and several areas are denied access to gas. 
Many countries are eying the province, which is rich in oil, gas, copper and gold reserves and has an important geopolitical position. Of the planned Chinese investment, Balochistan has a share of 38%, aimed at generating economic activities including infrastructure development, creating jobs for the locals and bringing an end to anti-state activities. 
For importers, the Gwadar Port will help save millions of dollars in demurrage cost. At present, oil suppliers and other companies have to pay hefty demurrage charges to shipping companies as ships have to wait for several days before getting a berth due to port congestion. 
Iranian investment 
After the Chinese came to Gwadar, Iran unveiled plans to set up the world’s largest oil refinery with capacity of 400,000 barrels per day at a cost of $8 billion. It also expressed interest in establishing power plants at the port. 
However, the US pressure against the Iran-Pakistan pipeline stalled the refinery project, which could have met not only Pakistan’s oil needs, but also provided the surplus for export to China. 
According to officials, China meets 50% of its oil demand from the Middle East, from where the supply line to China travels over 10,000 km through the Dubai-Shanghai-Urumqi route.
On the contrary, the crude oil processed and refined at the Gwadar oil refinery can be exported to China through the shortest possible route – Dubai-Gwadar-Urumqi – spanning about 3,600 km. For this, an oil pipeline has been proposed through the energy corridor up to western China via Karakoram Highway and Khunjrab Bypass. 
As part of the Pak-China Economic Corridor that will turn Pakistan into a hub of regional cooperation, the Gwadar Port will be connected through road, rail and fibre links to China to enhance trade between the two countries. Oil and gas pipelines are also part of the corridor over the long run, which will boost economic activities in Balochistan, officials say. 
So far, work on the port has been slow because of poor condition of roads. This underlines the need for the government to lay railway tracks from Gwadar to other ports of the country, which will save freight and encourage importers to bring cargoes through Gwadar. 
Published in The Express Tribune, June 23rd, 2014.
Like Business on Facebook, follow @TribuneBiz on Twitter to stay informed and join in the conversation.

Monday, June 16, 2014

Iran and the US cooperation in Iraq: hope for the future?


The Islamist State of Iraq and Syria (ISIS) now controls parts of Iraq that were already out of Baghdad's control so their advance, so far, doesn't mean much, except to the people who are dead or now subject to the Saudi Wahhabis-style of Islam, the mot fanatical of all.

For news about how developments are affecting Kurds, see Forbes, Rudaw, and The Huffington Post.  The news is schetchy and grim, so far.

Iran will not allow oil-rich Basra, where many Shiites live, to fall into Sunni Jihadist hands.  I don't know how strongly Iran feels about Baghdad.

Overall, except for the human suffering -- not a minor "except" -- events are developing in ways that are good for the United States, Western Europe, and Pakistan, and are unfavorable to China.  And there is finally a Bad Guy in Syria that the West can oppose, on the ground that ISIS is worse even than Assad.

 Meanwhile, Netanyahuists chew their fingernails to the bone and rational Israelis cross their fingers in hope of avoiding War with Iran.  Watch out for the cornered creature: he's dangerous.

d

Deutsche WelleDaily update ⋅ June 16, 2014IRAQ

US Secretary of State won't rule out cooperation with Iran in Iraq crisis 
US Secretary of State John Kerry will not rule out cooperation with Iran against Islamist militants in Iraq. Meanwhile, Saudi Arabia has called on Shiite-led Baghdad to form a national unity government with Sunnis.
In an interview with Yahoo News on Monday, Secretary of State Kerry said that he "wouldn't rule out anything that would be constructive" to stop the rapid advance of the Islamist State of Iraq and Syria (ISIS), including military cooperation with Iran. 
Kerry's comments come after Iranian President Hassan Rouhani also expressed openness to cooperating with Washington in Iraq. Rouhani told a news conference on Saturday that "we can think about it, if we see America starts confronting the terrorist groups in Iraq and elsewhere." 
Iraqi Prime Minister Nouri al-Maliki's Shiite-led government is closely allied with both Iran and the US. Cooperation between Washington and Tehran in Iraq would signal a major thaw in their otherwise adversarial relationship, just as they seek to conclude a final deal over the Islamic Republic's disputed nuclear program by the end of July. 
Washington broke off official diplomatic relations with Tehran in 1979, after Iranian revolutionaries stormed the American embassy and held 66 US diplomats hostage for 444 days. 
US 'deeply committed' to Iraq
n his Monday interview, Kerry went on to say that the US was "deeply committed to the integrity of Iraq as a country." The Secretary of State said that Washington may carry out drone strikes against ISIS. 
According to US broadcaster CNN, Washington deployed the amphibious transport dock ship USS Mesa Verde to the Persian Gulf on Monday. The warship reportedly had 550 marines on board. But US President Barack Obama has ruled out sending ground troops to Iraq. The Pentagon has alreadydeployed an aircraft carrier, the USS George H.W. Bush, to the region.
ISIS militants reportedly captured Tal Afar on Monday. The northern city, located 548 kilometers (340 miles) northwest of Baghdad and 70 kilometers west of Mosul, has a predominantly ethnic Turkmen population of 200,000. 
On Friday, Kerry said that President Obama would take "timely decisions" about how to address the advance of ISIS, an al Qaeda splinter group. 
Saudis call for Iraqi unity 
Meanwhile, Saudi Arabia has called on Iraq's Shiite-led government to reach out to the country's minority Sunni community. Riyadh said that Baghdad should form a national unity government as quickly as possible. 
The Saudis accused Iraqi Prime Minister al-Maliki of triggering the current crisis by pursuing "sectarian and exclusionary" policies. Iraq's Sunnis have accused al-Maliki of using counterterrorism as pretense to discriminate against and oppress their minority community. 
Reports from the region have suggested that some Sunni communities in Iraq are welcoming ISIS advances, viewing the group as a possible defender against the Shiite-led central government in Baghdad.
slk/jm (AP, AFP, dpa, Reuters) 

Saturday, May 31, 2014

Obama's West Point Speech and the three capitalists' internecine struggles

Last Wednesday, President Obama spoke to the West Point graduating class.  The text is after the jump.

The speech was billed as a new departure on foreign policy.  It seemed to me as a speech designed as ammunition for Democrats in the Fall Congressional elections, and as it should have been.  Now is not the time for new, challenging ideas.  Now is the time to increase Democrats' control of Congress.  The speech, I thought, effectively rebutted the Tea Party and McCain-Graham bickering: unwise demagoguery.

I didn't see anything in the speech that was objectionable, and much that was conventional and nevertheless wise, and a great relief after a decades of Republican warmongering.

Here's the Guardian's take, not flattering, not damning, on the  speech. The Guardian's mild objections are as much beside the real point as was the speech itself.  What I wanted to hear was how we are to help moderate the three major centers of Capital when they have not adopted rules of normative behavior for themselves.  Therein lies the greatest danger in the world.

For more information on the lawless Capitalist conflicts, se Slavoj Žižek's interview on the Guardian.

For the reactionary response to the President, se the Wall Street Journal's editorial.

Obama's speech marked the end of a war-laden chapter for the US – with little clear idea of what the next chapter should really mean. Photograph: Jim Watson / AFP / Getty

Even before President Obama spoke to the US military academy at West Point on Wednesday, the White House trumpeted his commencement address as offering a unifying vision of US foreign policy – one that is "both interventionist and internationalist, but not isolationist or unilateral".

With an introduction like that, it came as a welcome surprise that the speech was merely intelligible. I liked the anti-thoughtless-intervention line – "Just because we have the best hammer does not mean that every problem is a nail" – but much of the nearly hour-long speech was a dull checklist of world problems (and the UN Law of the Sea Convention!), most addressed by the routine oversimplifications required on such occasions.

Obama's "vision" was peppered with confusing vocabulary about "realists" and "interventionists", both depicted as straw men, and too many predictable bromides about international cooperation, democracy and "human dignity". And I say this as a former speechwriter who also used to lean on such filler.

There was no over-arching theme to this rhetoric, save Obama's recommitment to American exceptionalism ("with every fiber of my being") and his rejection of mindless invasions. Not much to disagree with there, but not much new either. One couldn't avoid the impression that this speech marked the end of a war-laden chapter for the US – with little clear idea of what the next chapter should really mean, save the repetitious evocation of "American leadership".

The leitmotif of Obama's foreign policy – and the first item of his West Point talk – is withdrawal, as Tuesday's announcement about drawdown in Afghanistan reconfirmed. So what about the rest of Obama's foreign policy?

Facts, not rhetoric, paint a picture of this administration's troubling and often counterproductive inconsistency abroad. There is some good, but there is plenty that's really bad.


From drones and emissions, to the South China Sea to Somalia to the Crimea and back again, it's not easy connect the many dots of America's foreign policies. Because aside from tortured rhetoric, unified they are not.

For the text of the President's speech,

Friday, May 9, 2014

South Sudan and China's dependence and new foreign policy

In the wake of the UN report on South Sudan of crimes against humanity committed by both sides in the revolution taking place there, I thought it useful to look again at China's stake and participation in South Sudan.

From Foreign Policy Review, April 24, 2p14

The disintegration of South Sudan, the world's newest country, is driving a foreign-policy shift in one of the world's oldest.
  • BY KEITH JOHNSON
  • APRIL 24, 2014
  • The maelstrom of violence in South Sudan shows no signs of abating, with rebel forces reportedly advancing on a pair of key oil-producing regions and massacred civilians piling up by the hundreds. The horrors have prompted outrage from senior officials at the United Nations and the United States -- but the biggest potential impact from the unrest could occur thousands of miles away, in Beijing.
The disintegration of the world's newest country is driving a profound shift in one of the world's oldest. China, which for decades has sought to pair globe-trotting economic ambitions with an inviolable "non-interference" approach to other countries' affairs, is departing from tradition to take an increasingly active role in the Sudan crisis.
China's African envoy, Zhong Jianhua, has blitzed the region in recent months trying to help craft a solution for South Sudan's internal strife, a stark contrast to the much-criticized, stand-off position China held just a few years ago when Khartoum ran roughshod over civilians but kept sending plenty of oil to Beijing. In February, Zhong told Reuters that China's hands-on approach to South Sudan represents a "new chapter" in Beijing's millennial foreign policy. Earlier this year, Zhong offered to facilitate mediations between the country's warring factions designed to wind down the fighting.
"China is taking a more active interest. They are trying to figure out just what it means to be a responsible, rising power," said Deborah Brautigam, an expert on Africa at Johns Hopkins School of Advanced International Studies.



"China is taking a more active interest. They are trying to figure out just what it means to be a responsible, rising power," said Deborah Brautigam, an expert on Africa at Johns Hopkins School of Advanced International Studies. "Right now, Sudan is kind of the test case for how do you do shuttle diplomacy, how do you do negotiations, how do you try to be a peacekeeper, how do you take on a greater global role."
Beijing has already sharply ramped up its participation in U.N. peacekeeping activities and other international endeavors that it once denounced as interference in the sovereign affairs of other states. China is the biggest single contributor of U.N. peacekeepers, but they have almost always played support roles far from the front lines. Last year, however, China dispatched combat troops to Mali to help reduce tensions in the country's restive north, a first for Beijing.
To be sure, Beijing's willingness to inject itself into the South Sudanese crisis is driven by the simple fact that China buys almost 80 percent of South Sudanese oil exports and has watched with alarm as the current fighting has crippled the country's ability to produce and export oil to customers in Asia. Oil production in both Sudans has dropped from a peak of about 480,000 barrels a day in 2010 to about 160,000 barrels today, and even that last bit is under pressure from rebels in South Sudan, who have ordered international oil companies to pack up and leave as part of a strategy to cut off the main economic lifeline of the South Sudanese government.
China may also not have much of a choice. The cease-fire in South Sudan brokered in early 2014 imploded in the last week, with rebels advancing on key cities in oil-producing regions and slaughtering civilians as they went. The political nature of the fighting -- which pits Salva Kiir's South Sudanese government forces against rebels led by Riek Machar -- has by some accounts descended into an ethnic bloodletting. China has been caught in the middle; a pair of its oil workers were abducted by Machar's forces last week and Chinese oil firms have been told to leave the country.
The U.N. and the South Sudanese government blamed Machar's rebel forces for the purported slaughter of hundreds of civilians in the atrocities in the oil capital of Bentiu; Machar denied his troops were responsible. Samantha Power, the U.S. ambassador to the U.N., decried the violence on Thursday, calling it "outrageous" and saying that "the world's newest state is clearly on a precipice."
China's traditional interests in both Sudan and South Sudan, and its newfound interest as a mediator, were on full display in the wake of the attacks. China's foreign ministry on Wednesday "strongly condemned" the killings in Bentiu and called on "relevant parties in South Sudan to resolve their issues by pushing forward political dialogue and achieve reconciliation." But the ministry also called on South Sudan's government to better protect Chinese oil firms and workers there after the two workers were abducted last week.
Oil markets are not panicking about the interruptions to South Sudanese production the way they did late last year when rebels first threatened the country's oil fields. That is partly because escalating tensions in Ukraine weigh more heavily on energy markets, but also because South Sudan's oil sector has essentially gone walkabout since the country achieved independence from the north in 2011.
Oil production has fallen by half, even in relatively peaceful times, and oil exports have fallen even further due to disputes between Juba and Khartoum over how to share the proceeds of oil exports; the only pipeline to the sea goes north through Sudan. That is bad news for South Sudan, which the World Bank describes as "the most oil dependent country in the world," with oil accounting for about 97 percent of government revenues.
Despite the relatively paltry quantities, South Sudan's oil is still important to China, the world's biggest oil importer. In 2011, China bought about 80 percent of South Sudan's exports, or roughly 260,000 barrels a day; that provided 5 percent of China's crude oil imports. In 2012, the latest year for which full data is available, South Sudan exported about 50,000 barrels a day to China, or 1 percent of that country's imports. In percentage terms, South Sudan -- when its export capacity is at full blast -- provides a greater share of Chinese oil imports than Kuwait or Iraq do for the United States, underscoring its importance as a long-term source of supply for Beijing.
In the past, that kind of economic interest shaped China's view of Sudan as well as most other countries in which it did business. For years, China invested in, and bought oil, from the outcast regime of Sudanese president Omar al-Bashir; China also had friendly relations with a host of other rogue nations, from Libya to North Korea and Myanmar, that faced a battery of sanctions and other restrictions imposed by the West.
Much of that began to change in 2011. The civil uprising in Libya forced China to rethink its support for Muammar al-Qaddafi, and in fact China supported modest United Nations sanctions on leading Libyan officials. The hurried evacuation of Chinese civilians from Libya that year also brought home to Beijing the need to match security capabilities with its investment reach, lessons which are being applied in the rest of Africa today.
Likewise, the creation of South Sudan as an independent state in 2011 forced Beijing to recalibrate its relations with Khartoum and Juba, since most of the oil fields are in the newly independent south.
To be sure, oil still looms large in China's view of what's at stake in the Sudan crisis; last year, Princeton Lyman, the former U.S. envoy to South Sudan, criticized China for worrying more about the secure supply of crude than finding a solution to South Sudan's political problems. But in general, U.S. diplomats working in South Sudan have praised China's newfound political engagement.
So far, China's active diplomacy to find a solution for South Sudan's domestic woes has not been repeated in other countries. Beijing has maintained a relatively hands-off role regarding the crises in Syria and Ukraine, and China's forays into Middle East diplomacy have been limited to ensuring the free flow of energy resources, rather than dabbling in internal politics.
Still, the Sudan experiment could well serve as a template for China's future foreign policy, as the country learns how to leverage its influence rather than just its economic heft, Brautigam said.
"They'll do it in one place, and experiment, and learn from that, and I think that's what they're doing in Sudan," she said.

Sunday, May 4, 2014

The New Silk Road


First is a news article from the Express Tribune, with the International New York Times.  It describes current a propose economic cooperation between Pakistan and China.  There is much talk of mutual friendship.

Mentioned by the Chinese ambassador are

Neelum Jhelum Hydropower Project, t
he largest man-made object
 in the world.

Proposed routes for both TAPA, s
upported by the US and China, 
and IP, weakly supported by China and vigorously opposed by the US.

Feasibility studies for a railroad link from the Chinese-owned Gwadar  deep-water port in southern Pakistan to China have been let by China and Pakistan.. China sees both financial and strategic advantages to the railway:  strategic, because oil could be transported from the Persian Gulf, undeterred by the US Fifth Fleet.


The second, from the Center for Global Development, details US economic aid to Pakistan over time.  In general, a lot of money went for "security", and the aid money has not been productively spent.

Pakistani are said to hate Americans, in part because of the drum-beat of hatred toward the West in the Saud-funded Madrases scattered throughout Pakistan; and in part because the "collateral damage" of US drone strikes raise intense animosity from the extended families, numbering millions, of those killed or wounded or financially ruined.  See, e.g., A Refusal to Mourn the Death, by Fire, of a Child in Yemen.

We could pressure the Saudi to change their drumbeat to a pro-Western one and it would be a major effort, probably including military action.  The Saudis rule over a minority population with unrivaled ferocity and they fear the consequences of Democracy and the Rule of Law above all things. 


There is no reason why the US must take all  the burn for the drone strikes, except that we want to keep a monopoly on drone technology for a while longer. Islamic radicals harm Western Europe, Russia, and China much more than they harm the US, and our drone strikes protect the World; only we take the born for them.

That burn is a necessary concomitant to global hegemony; I'm pleased that we are the "Hedgemon" (there is such a word:  'one (as a political state) possessing hegemony'"); and not please with the consequences.  

We could become great friends with Pakistan and friendship would greatly bolster our competitive advantage over China, but for the drone strikes, which we could share with other nations, and but for our decades-long commitment to prevent Iran from exporting its natural resources.  Pakistan desperately needs Iranian natural gas, and the US won't even let Ernst and Whinny participate in financing he Pakistan portion of a pipeline 

We have prevailed so far in boxing Iran, for nothing of value to the Nation in return, though the value to the Saudi and their economic  friends is great (see US, Chevron, China, and Central Asia); we will not prevail in the long run,; the world hunger for oil is too great.  And we will have lost a lot when we finally fail.


China has a natural advantage in its relations with all of Central Asia: the nations share the same land mass.  The US is protected from foreign wars, so far, be giant oceans, and disadvantaged by those same oceans when it comes to exerting influence over Asian nations.  Our great Navy of-sets the disadvantages, and cannot match the Chinese Gwadar port in South Pakistan, or an express highway running from China to Pakistan.




Thursday, April 24, 2014

Fatah and Hamas reconsile, displeasing Israel and he US

I am puzzled by the US response to Reconciliation. I don't see how any "peace agreement" that fails to include Hamas can result in peace.  Labeling Ha,as a
"terrorist organization" is useless cant. This quotation from the article below states a position I agree with.  Until we learn the terms of the reconciliation agreement, the US should withhold judgment.

Durell

Tamara Cofman Wittes, director of the Saban Center for Middle East Policy at the Brookings Institution in Washington, said the implications depended on the precise terms of the reconciliation, which have yet to be revealed.

“If, and it is a big ‘if,’ Hamas comes under the P.L.O. umbrella in such a way that it accedes to the P.L.O.’s recognition of Israel and the P.L.O.’s signed agreements with Israel,” she said, “that would be historic.”

“What would make it horrible is if Hamas were to join the P.L.O. without those kinds of commitments,” Ms. Wittes added. “Then it calls into question the P.L.O.’s commitments that it has already made.”
New York Times

MIDDLE EAST

Palestinian Rivals Announce Unity Pact, Drawing U.S. and Israeli Rebuke
By JODI RUDOREN and MICHAEL R. GORDONA
PRIL 23, 2014

JERUSALEM — The faltering Middle East peace process was thrown into further jeopardy on Wednesday, with Israel and the United States harshly condemning a new deal announced by feuding Palestinian factions, including the militant group Hamas, to repair their seven-year rift.

Israel canceled a negotiating session scheduled for Wednesday night shortly after leaders of the Palestine Liberation Organization joined hands with their rivals from Hamas at a celebratory ceremony in the Gaza Strip.

“Whoever chooses Hamas does not want peace,” the Israeli prime minister, Benjamin Netanyahu, said in a statement, describing the group as “a murderous terrorist organization that calls for the destruction of Israel.”

The unity pact, coming days before the April 29 expiration date for the American-brokered peace talks that have been the mainstay of Secretary of State John Kerry’s tenure, surprised officials in Washington, which, like Israel, deems Hamas a terrorist group and forbids direct dealings with it. After months of intensive shuttle diplomacy in which Mr. Kerry relentlessly pursued the peace processand even dangled the possibility of releasing an American convicted of spying for Israel to salvage the lifeless talks, his spokeswoman, Jen Psaki, called the Palestinian move “disappointing” and the timing “troubling.”

The Hamas prime minister, Ismail Haniya, center, and Azzam al-Ahmad, left, a senior Fatah official who headed the P.L.O. delegation to Gaza, at a news conference on Wednesday in Gaza City. CreditWissam Nassar for The New York Times
“Any Palestinian government must unambiguously and explicitly commit to nonviolence, recognition of the state of Israel, and acceptance of previous agreements and obligations between the parties,” Ms. Psaki said, citing conditions Hamas has repeatedly rejected. “It’s hard to see how Israel can be expected to negotiate with a government that does not believe in its right to exist.”

Hamas and Fatah, the faction that dominates the P.L.O., have signed several similar accords before that were not carried out, so it remained unclear whether Wednesday’s deal promised a real resolution or a replay of an old movie.

Some analysts saw the step primarily as a tactic by President Mahmoud Abbas of the Palestinian Authority to pressure Israel to make concessions as the clock winds down on extending the fraught negotiations. He said in statement that “there is no contradiction at all” between reconciliation and negotiation, adding, “We are totally committed to establishing a just and comprehensive peace based on the two-state principle.”

Other experts noted that Palestinian political conditions have drastically changed since the signing of previous agreements, which could lead both parties to make the compromises necessary to put this one into action. Hamas has been in a deep political and economic crisis since the military-backed government took over Egypt last summer and largely cut ties with Gaza. Mr. Abbas, at 79, is looking for a legacy and an exit strategy.

Reconciliation is deeply resonant among Palestinians and could revive the president’s sagging popularity.

“It’s not bad for both sides — it is bad for the peace process,” said Shimrit Meir, an Israeli analyst of Palestinian politics and editor of The Source, an Arabic news website. “It is simply rude, in diplomatic language, when Kerry is doing his last heroic effort to save the peace process, to reward it with reconciliation with a terrorist group. I think this is a message, and it’s very blunt.”

Something like this is a prerequisite to peace, as a practical matter. Or do negotiations with an entity that effectively represents only a fraction of the people and territories involved make any sense?

Beyond the damage to the peace talks, joining forces with Hamas could cost the Palestinians millions of dollars in financial aid from the United States and Europe, and prompt a host of retaliatory actions by Israel.

Even as the deal was being announced, there were other signs of tension. An Israeli airstrike hit northern Gaza, apparently missing the militant on a motorcycle it was aiming for and wounding 12 Palestinians, including two children, according to Gaza health officials. Later Wednesday evening, two rockets fired from Gaza landed in open areas of southern Israel.  [Inexcusable.  Comment by d]

The schism between Hamas and Fatah began in 2007, with a brief but bloody civil war that followed a failed unity government after Hamas’s victory in 2006 Palestinian elections. It left Palestinian territory divided, with Hamas ruling Gaza, the impoverished and isolated coastal expanse, and the Fatah-dominated Palestinian Authority governing the larger and more populous West Bank.

Dreams of reconciliation have been repeatedly dashed, after much-trumpeted agreements signed in Cairo in 2011 and Doha in 2012were never carried out.

“Sorry to say that we are familiar with such celebrations,” said Talal Okal, a Gaza political analyst. “I hope that this time will be more serious, but to be more serious is to go directly and quickly to the first step, to let the people touch and see, not to hear only.”

On Wednesday afternoon, after two days of meetings at the home of the Hamas prime minister, Ismail Haniya, in Gaza City’s Beach refugee camp, the Palestinian leaders vowed to form a government of technocrats within five weeks that would prepare for long-overdue elections six months later.

“I announce to our people the news that the years of split are over,” Mr. Haniya said triumphantly.

Azzam al-Ahmad, a senior Fatah official who headed the P.L.O. delegation to Gaza, said he hoped the deal would be “a true beginning and a true partnership.”

Ziad Abu Amr, deputy prime minister of the Palestinian Authority and a close aide to Mr. Abbas, said the new deal came about because “the situation has become more demanding and the pressures are rising.” He cited Egypt’s frequent closing of the Rafah border crossing, Gaza’s gateway to the world, which he said a technocratic government could reverse, as well as domestic political concerns.

“It’s a psychological and national issue that Palestinians feel they are united,” Mr. Abu Amr said. “This split is hurting them.”

He and other Palestinian leaders dismissed Israel’s threats and said reconciliation was an internal matter, noting that the presence of extreme right-wing members in Israel’s governing coalition had not stopped Palestinians from participating in the peace talks. They also pointed out that some Israeli leaders had questioned Mr. Abbas’s ability to deliver a peace deal with Hamas controlling Gaza.

“Mr. Netanyahu and his government were using Palestinian division as an excuse not to make peace,” said Saeb Erekat, the chief Palestinian negotiator. “Now they want to use Palestinian reconciliation as an excuse for the same purpose. This is utterly absurd.”

Israel’s cabinet planned to meet Thursday to plan its next steps. Dore Gold, a senior adviser to Mr. Netanyahu, called the Palestinian deal “a real game changer,” and said, “You cannot have a serious peace process with Hamas inside.”

Tzipi Livni, Israel’s chief negotiator, said the reconciliation was a “very problematic development.”

Some Washington-based Middle East experts, who had long thought Mr. Kerry’s efforts to be an uphill struggle given the yawning gaps between Israeli and Palestinian positions on fundamental issues, said Wednesday’s developments boded ill.

Aaron David Miller, a former State Department peace negotiator, said Mr. Abbas had “bought peace at home in exchange for significant tensions with the Israelis” and called the move “one more nail to a peace-process coffin that is rapidly being closed.”

Dennis B. Ross, another former American peace envoy, said that the move could make Mr. Abbas “less susceptible to a domestic backlash for continuing the process with the Israelis,” but that “the timing is very problematic — when the process is already faltering, this could be a body blow.”

Tamara Cofman Wittes, director of the Saban Center for Middle East Policy at the Brookings Institution in Washington, said the implications depended on the precise terms of the reconciliation, which have yet to be revealed.

“If, and it is a big ‘if,’ Hamas comes under the P.L.O. umbrella in such a way that it accedes to the P.L.O.’s recognition of Israel and the P.L.O.’s signed agreements with Israel,” she said, “that would be historic.”

“What would make it horrible is if Hamas were to join the P.L.O. without those kinds of commitments,” Ms. Wittes added. “Then it calls into question the P.L.O.’s commitments that it has already made.”

Jodi Rudoren reported from Jerusalem, and Michael R. Gordon from Washington. Fares Akram contributed reporting from Gaza City, and Isabel Kershner and Said Ghazali from Jerusalem.

∼∼∼∼∼∼∼∼∼∼

Timor mortis, conturbat me (The fear of death confounds me.)  The confounding fear of death is the  moving factor in all Israeli and Palestinian dealings.  Until that fear if faced with courage, misery will result.  Durell

Tuesday, April 8, 2014

The reasons for war, a survey with unflattering commentary

Not for the proud man apart   
From the raging moon I write   
On these spindrift pages   
Nor for the towering dead
With their nightingales and psalms   
But for the lovers, their arms   
Round the griefs of the ages,   
Who pay no praise or wages   
Nor heed my craft or art.
Dylan Thomas

Human animals face extinction from two things we do to ourselves:
   War and overpopulation.  Overpopulation is reviewed in another post.

Attempting to understand why we slaughter one another with such abandon, and have done for all of recorded history† is worthy, even if only becomes the attempt a part of the cultural background that impels us.

In the article reprinted here, two eminent scholars summarize the result of their investigation of the reasons we kill ourselves in War so freely.

The summery is interesting and compelling, if the authors' unstated assumptions are correct.  One assumption is that there is such an animal as a "rational man".  The criminal law and the tort law make the same assumption;  in both cases, an information revolution begin by Freud and Jung and others, which continues today, is ignored.  I cannot speak for economics, which is the authors' main thrust, but for law, the failure to consider current about human beings has lead to many bad decisions and bad results.  I suspect much the same is true or economics.

We have been three-quarters of a century without a world war, and without a nuclear war.  I suspect that billions of individual women and men, living in hundreds of communities, have individually decided that they will no longer support mass slaughter of our kind, and war as we have known it for all human history will morph into commercial struggles for power and wealth.

I also suspect that, while billions of us no loner support mass slaughter, most of us prefer a hierarchical structure to lead us, leading -- I fear -- to a universal dictatorship.

When billions of us, in time, watch power  accumulate in fewer and fewer hands, also reject government by monopoly or oligopoly, we will opt for a more open form of government, likely unknowable, currently.

Interlines to the summary are by me and are in italics,  and all images are posted by me and not by the authors.  Footnotes are omitted.  The full article is here.

 Here is a list of recent wars and casualties.  The list does not mention the wounded, nor the hundreds of millions of persons heart-broken and thrusting for revenge; or the hundreds of mullions of displaced persons.
Wars and Casualties of the 20th and 21st Centuries
(slowly extending it back to the 19th century as i find data)by Piero Scaruffi
160 million people died in wars during the 20th century
(See also Modern Genocides)
TM, ®, Copyright © 2009 Piero Scaruffi All rights reserved.

1860-65: USA civil war (628,000) 1886-1908: Belgium-Congo Free State (8 million) 1898: USA-Spain & Philippines (220,000) 1899-02: British-Boer war (100,000) 1899-03: Colombian civil war (120,000) 1899-02: Philippines vs USA (20,000) 1900-01: Boxer rebels against Russia, Britain, France, Japan, USA against rebels (35,000) 1903: Ottomans vs Macedonian rebels (20,000) 1904: Germany vs Namibia (65,000) 1904-05: Japan vs Russia (150,000) 1910-20: Mexican revolution (250,000) 1911: Chinese Revolution (2.4 million) 1911-12: Italian-Ottoman war (20,000) 1912-13: Balkan wars (150,000) 1915: the Ottoman empire slaughters Armenians (1.2 million) 1915-20: the Ottoman empire slaughters 500,000 Assyrians 1916-23: the Ottoman empire slaughters 350,000 Greek Pontians and 480,000 Anatolian Greeks1914-18: World War I (20 million) 1916: Kyrgyz revolt against Russia (120,000) 1917-21: Soviet revolution (5 million) 1917-19: Greece vs Turkey (45,000) 1919-21: Poland vs Soviet Union (27,000) 1928-37: Chinese civil war (2 million) 1931: Japanese Manchurian War (1.1 million) 1932-33: Soviet Union vs Ukraine (10 million) 1932: "La Matanza" in El Salvador (30,000) 1932-35: "Guerra del Chaco" between Bolivia and Paraguay (117.500) 1934: Mao's Long March (170,000) 1936: Italy's invasion of Ethiopia (200,000) 1936-37: Stalin's purges (13 million) 1936-39: Spanish civil war (600,000) 1937-45: Japanese invasion of China (500,000) 1939-45: World War II (55 million) including holocaust and Chinese revolution 1946-49: Chinese civil war (1.2 million) 1946-49: Greek civil war (50,000) 1946-54: France-Vietnam war (600,000) 1947: Partition of India and Pakistan (1 million) 1947: Taiwan's uprising against the Kuomintang (30,000) 1948-1958: Colombian civil war (250,000) 1948-1973: Arab-Israeli wars (70,000) 1949-: Indian Muslims vs Hindus (20,000) 1949-50: Mainland China vs Tibet (1,200,000) 1950-53: Korean war (3 million) 1952-59: Kenya's Mau Mau insurrection (20,000) 1954-62: French-Algerian war (368,000) 1958-61: Mao's "Great Leap Forward" (38 million) 1960-90: South Africa vs Africa National Congress (?) 1960-96: Guatemala's civil war (200,000) 1961-98: Indonesia vs West Papua/Irian (100,000) 1961-2003: Kurds vs Iraq (180,000) 1962-75: Mozambique Frelimo vs Portugal (10,000) 1962-75: Angolan FNLA & MPLA vs Portugal (50,000) 1964-73: USA-Vietnam war (3 million) 1965: second India-Pakistan war over Kashmir 1965-66: Indonesian civil war (250,000) 1966-69: Mao's "Cultural Revolution" (11 million) 1966-: Colombia's civil war (31,000) 1967-70: Nigeria-Biafra civil war (800,000) 1968-80: Rhodesia's civil war (?) 1969-: Philippines vs the communist Bagong Hukbong Bayan/ New People's Army (40,000) 1969-79: Idi Amin, Uganda (300,000) 1969-02: IRA - Norther Ireland's civil war (3,000) 1969-79: Francisco Macias Nguema, Equatorial Guinea (50,000) 1971: Pakistan-Bangladesh civil war (500,000) 1972-2014: Philippines vs Muslim separatists (Moro Islamic Liberation Front, etc) (150,000) 1972: Burundi's civil war (300,000) 1972-79: Rhodesia/Zimbabwe's civil war (30,000) 1974-91: Ethiopian civil war (1,000,000) 1975-78: Menghitsu, Ethiopia (1.5 million) 1975-79: Khmer Rouge, Cambodia (1.7 million) 1975-89: Boat people, Vietnam (250,000) 1975-87: civil war in Lebanon (130,000) 1975-87: Laos' civil war (184,000) 1975-2002: Angolan civil war (500,000) 1976-83: Argentina's military regime (20,000) 1976-93: Mozambique's civil war (900,000) 1976-98: Indonesia-East Timor civil war (600,000) 1976-2005: Indonesia-Aceh (GAM) civil war (12,000) 1977-92: El Salvador's civil war (75,000) 1979: Vietnam-China war (30,000) 1979-88: the Soviet Union invades Afghanistan (1.3 million) 1980-88: Iraq-Iran war (435,000) 1980-92: Sendero Luminoso - Peru's civil war (69,000) 1984-: Kurds vs Turkey (35,000) 1981-90: Nicaragua vs Contras (60,000) 1982-90: Hissene Habre, Chad (40,000) 1983-: Sri Lanka's civil war (70,000) 1983-2002: Sudanese civil war (2 million) 1986-: Indian Kashmir's civil war (60,000) 1987-: Palestinian Intifada (4,500) 1988-2001: Afghanistan civil war (400,000) 1988-2004: Somalia's civil war (550,000) 1989-: Liberian civil war (220,000) 1989-: Uganda vs Lord's Resistance Army (30,000) 1991: Gulf War - large coalition against Iraq to liberate Kuwait (85,000) 1991-97: Congo's civil war (800,000) 1991-2000: Sierra Leone's civil war (200,000) 1991-2009: Russia-Chechnya civil war (200,000) 1991-94: Armenia-Azerbaijan war (35,000) 1992-96: Tajikstan's civil war war (50,000) 1992-96: Yugoslavian wars (260,000) 1992-99: Algerian civil war (150,000) 1993-97: Congo Brazzaville's civil war (100,000) 1993-2005: Burundi's civil war (200,000) 1994: Rwanda's civil war (900,000) 1995-: Pakistani Sunnis vs Shiites (1,300) 1995-: Maoist rebellion in Nepal (12,000) 1998-: Congo/Zaire's war - Rwanda and Uganda vs Zimbabwe, Angola and Namibia (3.8 million) 1998-2000: Ethiopia-Eritrea war (75,000) 1999: Kosovo's liberation war - NATO vs Serbia (2,000) 2001-: Afghanistan's liberation war - USA & UK vs Taliban (40,000) 2001-: Nigeria vs Boko Haram (1700) 2002-: Cote d'Ivoire's civil war (1,000) 2003-11: Second Iraq-USA war - USA, UK and Australia vs Saddam Hussein's regime and Shiite squads and Sunni extremists (160,000) 2003-09: Sudan vs JEM/Darfur (300,000) 2004-: Sudan vs SPLM & Eritrea (?) 2004-: Yemen vs Shiite Muslims (?) 2004-: Thailand vs Muslim separatists (3,700) 2007-: Pakistan vs PAkistani Taliban (38,000) 2012-: Iraq's civil war after the withdrawal of the USA (?) 2012-: Syria's civil war (130,000)Arab-Israeli warsI (1947-49): 6,373 Israeli and 15,000 Arabs dieII (1956): 231 Israeli and 3,000 Egyptians dieIII (1967): 776 Israeli and 20,000 Arabs dieIV (1973): 2,688 Israeli and 18,000 Arabs dieIntifada I (1987-92): 170 Israelis and 1,000 PalestiniansIntifada II (2000-03): 700 Israelis and 2,000 PalestiniansIsrael-Hamas war (2008): 1,300 Palestinians


The Reasons for Wars – an Updated Survey

Matthew O. Jackson and Massimo Morelli Revised: December 2009

Forthcoming in the Handbook on the Political Economy of War, edited by Chris Coyne, Elgar Publishing . . . .


Matthew O. Jackson: Department of Economics, Stanford University, Stanford, California 94305-6072, and external faculty member of the Santa Fe Institute, USA. Email: jacksonm@stanford.edu, http://www.stanford.edu/~jacksonm

Massimo Morelli: Columbia University and European University Institute. Email:
mm3331@columbia.edu http://www.columbia.edu/cu/polisci/fac- bios/morelli/faculty.html1. 


Introduction

Why do wars occur and recur, especially in cases when the decisions involved are made by careful and rational actors? There are many answers to this question. Given the importance of the question, and the wide range of answers, it is essential to have a perspective on the various sources of conflict. In this chapter we provide a critical overview of the theory of war. In particular, we provide not just a taxonomy of causes of conflict, but also some insight into the necessity of and interrelation between different factors that lead to war.

Is Dick Cheney a careful and rational actor?

Is Donald Rumsfeld?
Or George W. Bush?

Let us offer a brief preview of the way in which we categorize causes of war. There are two prerequisites for a war between (rational) actors. One is that the costs of war cannot be overwhelmingly high. By that we mean that there must be some plausible situations in the eyes of the decision makers such that the anticipated gains from a war in terms of resources, power, glory, territory, and so forth exceed the expected costs of conflict, including expected damages to property and life. Thus, for war to occur with rational actors, at least one of the sides involved has to expect that the gains from the conflict will outweigh the costs incurred. Without this prerequisite there can be lasting peace.Second, as cogently argued by Fearon (1995), there has to be a failure in bargaining, so that for some reason there is an inability to reach a mutually advantageous and enforceable agreement. The main tasks in understanding war between rational actors are thus to see why bargaining fails and what incentives or circumstances might lead countries to arm in ways such that the expected benefits from war outweigh the costs for at least one of the sides.

". . . and life." The last in a list, perhaps intended to be comprehensive, of factors to be considered when rationally deciding to engage in War.  Not listed are: 
maiming, burning,limbs twitted 'til sinus give way, insanity, often for what i left of life --






Goya wan't just making things up . . . .





Also not considered is starvation, the loss of habitat, he injury to many forms of non-human life, and, perhaps most relevant, grief that the death of a loved-one brings, with its resultant anguish, tears, and thrust for vengeance, perpetrating War. 









 The caption to this image is
"A man of sorrows and acquainted with grief.'




"'Remembrance Day takes on a profoundly different meaning
 once you have seen what people in the Armed Forces risk,
 their plight, their lives after service, 



A good portion of our overview of the causes of war is thus spent discussing a framework of different bargaining failures. We emphasize that understanding sources of bargaining failure is not only useful as a categorization, but also because different types of failures lead to different conclusions about the types of wars that emerge, and particularly about things like the duration of war. We return to comment on this after discussing various reasons for bargaining failure. Below, we talk in detail about the following five reasons for bargaining failure:
1. Asymmetric information about the potential costs and benefits of war.

2. A lack of ability to enforce a bargaining agreement and/or a lack of the ability to credibly commit to abide by an agreement.

3. Indivisibilities of resources that might change hands in a war, so that not all potentially mutually beneficial bargaining agreements are feasible.

4. Agency problems, where the incentives of leaders differ from those of the populations that they represent.

5. Multilateral interactions where every potential agreement is blocked by some coalition of states or constituencies who can derail it.

To illustrate the importance of understanding which reason lies behind a conflict, note that if there is a lack of ability to enforce or commit to an agreement, then a war may last a long time. It will last until either one side has emerged victorious, or the situation has changed so that the costs of continued conflict have become overwhelmingly high for all sides. Such a lack of enforceable agreements is often one of the main ingredients leading to protracted wars. In contrast, suppose that enforceable and credible agreements are possible, but that the states start with asymmetric information, for instance, about the relative strength of one of the two countries. In such a case, there can be a bargaining failure which leads to war. However, in such a setting once war really begins the relative strengths of the countries can become clearer, and given that credible bargaining is possible and can avoid further costs of war the states could then reach an agreement to end the war. So, different durations of wars can correspond to different sources of bargaining failures. We expand on this below.
The chapter is organized as follows: For a clearer understanding of the boundaries of rationalist versus non rationalist explanations, we start by briefly discussing non-rationalist explanations in section 2. Section 3 provides a taxonomy of bargaining failures and how these relate to conflict; section 4 contains a discussion of which theories described in section 3 shed light on the observations of the democratic peace. In section 5 we report on the state of the literature on endogenous armaments and power and the implications for conflict and war.


2. The realm of rationality

Before proceeding to discuss various bargaining failures as causes of war, we discuss some of the alternative sources of conflict that are sometimes thought to fall into the realm of irrationality. We argue that many of these are more usefully viewed as being rational in nature, and hence the bargaining failure categorization still applies to many conflicts that are sometimes thought to be irrational. In order for our discussion to be as unambiguous as possible, we begin by clarifying what we mean when we dichotomize between rational and irrational actors. When we refer to a rational action by an agent we require that action to maximize the expected payoff to that agent out of the available actions and relative to the agent’s beliefs about the potential consequences of the actions. This does not necessarily require that the beliefs be accurate, nor that the payoffs of the individual agent correspond to what is best for the state or country that he or she might represent. This is a broader definition of a rationalist explanation than is usually understood in International Relations, where it is common to associate a rationalist approach to realist and neo-realist theories of conflict with unitary actors that are exclusively interested in material costs and benefits. Our broader definition should make it clear that what matters is that players, given the payoffs that they face from different outcomes, choose their actions to maximize it given their beliefs about the opponents’ actions, hence the qualification "material costs and benefits" is not necessary, nor it is necessary to confine the use of the rationalist approach to the world of unitary actors.

3 In order for this not to become a tautology, one has to be careful. An "irrational" act can always be rationalized simply by saying that it gave the agent taking it a high payoff for some intrinsic reason. Thus in order to have bite, the payoffs to agents for various actions have to have some natural specification. Although the distinction is thus partly semantic, or reliant on some idea of what natural payoffs should be, we still find it to be a useful dichotomy.

4

With this viewpoint in mind, let us discuss some causes of war that are often thought of as relying on some level of ``irrationality.’’ As we shall see, with our broad definition of rationality, even many of these may be interpreted as rational causes of war. This is not simply an issue of semantics, since the distinction has fundamental implications for how wars might be initiated, and if and how they can be avoided or terminated.

2.1 Religion

In principle, a war between two theocracies, or two states led by people of different religions, can be thought of as having rational explanations. It is a question of defining the objectives of the agents. For example, the goal might not be materially based, but might be based on the increasing the size of the population of one religion or eradicating another. In such situations, even with full commitment and bargaining opportunities, there might be no agreement that appeases an aggressor. One reason that one might place such motivations outside of the realm of "rationality," is that such objectives are often not put forth by a leader as if they are acting by choice, but instead leaders claim to be acting on behalf or under the direction of a higher being or religious code. Thus, the leaders in such settings do not necessarily view themselves as "optimizing" or "choosing" between paths but instead as following ordained directions. Perhaps even more importantly, from our perspective, such agents cannot be bargained with. That is, even if agreements are available and fully enforceable, such agents are driven by a specific goal that may be incompatible with the well-being or autonomy of another population. Thus, there is a critical distinction between a leader who is choosing and optimizing, even though the his or her rhetoric may be religious in nature, and a leader who believes that he or she acts simply as a channel for a higher being.
In this light, many wars that are thought of as being religious in nature can still be well-understood from a rational perspective. To make this point clear, let us discuss two prominent examples that are often considered to be at least partly religious wars: the crusades and the 30-year war.

5

Although the crusades were complicated by the fact that the aggressor was a coalition of national and sub-national armies, they fell under a common religious flag. Beyond the rhetoric, the commonality of interests within the Christian coalition can be doubted. As Fisher (1992) remarks about the interests of crusaders: "Undoubtedly, many of the Crusaders were inspired by a genuine religious motive next to their mundane concern for a share in the spoils. However, the idea of Christian unity failed again to achieve political reality. The Crusaders not only carved up the newly won territories in the East into petty principalities but also continued to struggle against each other in Europe. And they ultimately failed to hold the East precisely because they could not square their particular interests with the universal idea that had inspired them..." (Fischer 1992:438). "Thus, the politics of the Crusades, while showing that religious ideas can have some political effect, remained alliances circumscribed by the exigencies of power" (1992:443). Effectively, the crusades involved many factions and took place over many fronts and to a large extent involved attempts to gain or regain control of various territories, ranging from the Iberian peninsula, to Constantinople, to parts of the middle east including Jerusalem. The important aspect of this from our perspective is that the crusades took place at least partly due to a lack of ability to credibly commit to abide by agreements, to the multiplicity of factions involved on multiple fronts, and due to situations with great frictions in communication and in gaining information (e.g., see Runciman (1951-4)). Thus, the crusades can be partly understood from a combination of the rationalist perspectives that we discuss below.
Regarding the 30-year war, even though before 1618 there was an eruption of religious divisions within Europe emanating from multiple protestant reforms and movements, the religious motivation was used by some leaders to justify actions and to mobilize people, when again part of the instability derived from a multi-lateral power struggle and a lack of enforceable agreements. As argued by Gutmann (1988), a central reason for the failure of many settlement attempts was the difficulty of enforcing a new distribution of power that was so different from the official distribution of power defended by the papacy and imperial power. The Westphalia agreements that ended the war in 1648 cut the connections between some of the territorial and religious disputes, and the principles of autonomy and territory that were embodied in the agreement laid a foundation for modern states.


To establish religious tolerance Catholics and Protestants were co-mingled within some of the same territories, and religious leaders were prohibited from having authority over people in separate territories. Thus, although the 30-year war involved religious motivations, the various factions were also motivated by territory, peace, and autonomy, and were eventually able to find a rather complicated agreement that was self-sustaining.

The long-standing conflict between Israel and the Palestinians could be viewed as another instance of a religious conflict that is often given non-rationalist explanations. However, it may more usefully be viewed through a rationalist lens. One of the central difficulties in resolving this middle-eastern conflict is in finding a stable agreement that is credible in the long run on behalf of the many different factions that comprise the two sides of the conflict. Even though the Oslo peace accords followed land for peace principles as one would expect in a rationalist dispute, when violence resumed the blame was given to "fundamentalism" on various sides (a typical non-rationalist explanation). The rationalist explanation for conflict based on multilateral bargaining, which we discuss below, is a more useful lens with which to view this conflict. In this case, both the Israelis and the Palestinians consist of many different constituencies and so although it appears to be a bilateral conflict it is in fact multilateral. In such settings, it can be that even with fully rational individual actors, agreements are not possible since the states end up being inconsistent in their decision-making as they are collectively aggregating the preferences of many different actors. This rationalist explanation is one that we discuss in more detail below.

2.2 Revenge

Revenge is another reason for war that one would instinctively place within the set of non-rationalist explanations of war. It is important, however, to distinguish an emotional version of revenge from a version of what someone might call revenge in the context of a repeated game: the punishment phase involved in trigger strategies of one kind or another. It is the emotional version that falls within the non-rationalist explanations. Revenge in emotional terms involves actions motivated exclusively by anger for a past action, and not motivated by the potential incentive consequences, nor decided ex ante as part of an optimal strategy. Wars driven by revenge are also rare, although famous examples include the motivation of the Achaeans' in the Trojan war, at least according to the description in the Iliad.

2.3 Ethnic cleansing and other ideological mass killings

As in our discussion of religion, one could in principle rationalize the incentives to eliminate another ethnic group or minority ideological group by a desire to obtain a larger share of the social cake, in the present and/or in the future (see e.g. Esteban and Ray (2008)). Such ideologies are generally uncompromising and not justified by reasoned choice but by appealing to other principles.

Hitler had the affirmation of the dominance of his race as a primary objective. However, as much as ethnic domination and insanity were part of Hitler's motivations, part of the understanding of the Second World War involves seeing why conflict was not avoided through concessions, and there rationalist explanations can help. As we mention below, for example, the failure of the Munich Agreement was due to credible commitment problems, and would have failed even if ethnicity and insanity were not in the picture.

3. Bargaining Failures and War

As mentioned in the introduction, we see two necessary ingredients for a war between rational agents. First, the costs of war cannot be overwhelmingly high. That is, for war to occur, at least one of the two parties must see a net potential gain from war under some circumstances. Second, there must be some impediment to bargaining, so that an enforceable and credible agreement cannot be reached. Effectively, rational decision makers weigh gains and losses from war given their objectives, beliefs, environment and constraints, and so if a mutually advantageous agreement is possible they should reach it. In an important paper, Fearon (1995) points out the criticality of bargaining failure for war. Basically, if rational agents come to the table with mutually consistent beliefs about the potential outcome of a costly war, then they should be able to reach a bargain to avoid it. In such a situation states can agree to split resources as they are expected to be split by a war, and then gain the extra surplus of the avoided destruction and costs of war.

Thus, to really understand the multitude of ways that wars may occur, it is illuminating to provide a taxonomy of bargaining failures and their roles in wars. As pointed out in Fearon (1995), there are various ways in which such bargaining might fail. It might be that the agents do not have the same beliefs or expectations about the potential outcome of a war. It could also be that they cannot commit to abide by an agreement and that there are no external means of enforcing an agreement. It might be that resources are indivisible and so there is no way to realize the split of resources that are expected as an outcome of a war. Beyond these three ways that are central to Fearon's analysis, we add another two. It might also be that the agents who bargain or make decisions do not have the same payoffs as the states at large, so that their incentives are distorted from what might be mutually beneficial to the populations. Finally, when considering multilateral bargaining, it might be that there is no outcome that is stable against coalitional deviations from groups of countries. In this section we elaborate on these five sources of bargaining failure, and we integrate this picture with some of the recent advancements in the theory of war.

3.1 Asymmetric information and bargaining failures

Asymmetries of information can arise from a variety of sources. It could be an asymmetry of information about the relative strengths of the countries either because of differences in what they know about each other's armaments, quality of military personnel and tactics, determination, geography, political climate, or even just about the relative probability of different outcomes.

The possibility of a bargaining failure due to asymmetric information has a solid foundation in economics, and was made very clear in work by Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983). To see the basic insights in the context of war, suppose that there are two countries and one of them, referred to as country A, has unknown strength. In particular, suppose that country A can either be strong or weak with equal probability in the eyes of the other country. Imagine that war involves a relatively small cost, that the victor in a war gains control of all resources, and that war results in one of the two countries conquering the other. Suppose that if country A is strong then it wins a war with probability 3/4 and if it is weak it wins with probability 1/4. So, in order to always avoid a war, an agreement must provide the strong version of country A with at least 3/4 of all resources less the cost of war (in expectation, presuming it maximizes expected payoff).

Now the asymmetry of information enters: a weak version of country A cannot be distinguished from a strong one by country B. Thus if the strong version of country A always gets at least 3/4 of the resources less the cost of war, then since a weak version of the country cannot be distinguished from a strong version by country B, a weak version of country A must also expect at least 3/4 of the total resources less the cost of war, as it can mimic a strong version of the country and get a high payoff without risk of war. This means that country B must get at most 1/4 of all resources plus the cost of war. If the cost of war is low enough, then the country B is better off simply going to war and taking its chances rather than reaching such an unfavorable bargain. This is obviously a highly stylized example, but it encapsulates the difficulties with bargaining in the face of asymmetric information. Generally, it may be difficult for a weak country to pretend to be a strong one, but there can still be some degree of asymmetric information across countries and even lesser asymmetries can make it impossible to find agreements that all parties will agree to in all circumstances.

It is important to note that imperfect information about the opponent's resolve or strength is a source of conflict that does not require any violation of common knowledge of rationality. The above reasoning is such that all the actors are fully rational, understand the setting, and fully comprehend all of its implications. It is also clear that the countries would like to avoid the difficulty. In particular, a strong version of country A would like to be able to distinguish itself from the weak version. If it could credibly demonstrate its strength, that would solve the problem. That is, if strength can be revealed peacefully and credibly (even at some minor cost), then there is a bargain which works as follows: if country A reveals strength, then it gets 3/4 of all resources and if it does not reveal its strength then it is presumed to be weak and only gets 1/4 of all resources. This solves the incentive problem as the weak version of country A can no longer pretend to be strong. Weakness is presumed unless evidence is presented to the contrary. This provides some insight into why countries might be willing to demonstrate arms (for instance publicly testing nuclear devices, holding military parades and exercises in observable settings, and so forth). There might be other settings where hiding strength is advantageous because bargaining is precluded, but in settings where binding agreements can be reached there are powerful incentives for the strongest types to reveal their strength to distinguish themselves from weaker types and to cement their bargaining position. Moreover, this is not limited to settings with just two potential strengths. Even with many different gradations of strength, the strongest wants to reveal itself, and then the next strongest will want to reveal itself, and so forth and this then unravels so all but the weakest types want to distinguish themselves. So this is robust to much richer information environments than the example above.

With such asymmetries of information, whether war will occur will depend on the extent to which the private information of individuals can be credibly revealed or not as well as how relevant the private information is to forecasting the outcome of a war. If it is really impossible to fully and credibly reveal information and such information is critical to predicting the outcome of a potential war, it can be that bargaining will fail and war must be expected with at least some probability. An early paper providing a model of war decisions with asymmetrically informed countries, and pointing out that an uninformed country may sometimes have to go to war to avoid bluffing behavior by an informed country, is Brito and Intriligator (1985).

The form of information asymmetry discussed above concerns potential outcomes of a war. A second information-based reason for a bargaining failure is that agents have inconsistent beliefs. For example, it could be that two states each are optimistic and are convinced that they will benefit from a war. In these cases war can erupt, as long as the inconsistency of beliefs is large enough to compensate for the cost of war. For instance, if both parties expect to win a war with a high enough probability, then there would not exist any agreement that avoids war

The possibility and examples of wars that are attributed to such miscalculations or errors due to lack of information or to different

A third form of information asymmetry concerns incomplete information about the motivations of other agents. Here it is believed that there is some probability that the other actor might be irrational.This includes spiraling models such as those discussed in Waltz (1959) and Schelling (1963), and more recently Kydd (1997). These ideas have been elaborated and extended upon by Baliga and Sjöström (2004) and subsequent works. The idea common to these works is that even a small probability of being faced by an armed irrational foe can lead a rational country to arm to some level. In turn, this now means that either a foe who is irrational, or a foe who thinks that I might be irrational will be arming, and this then leads me to arm even more, and this feedback continues to build. Depending on the specifics of the payoffs to arming and potential conflict, it can be that the rational countries each arm to very high levels and are ready to attack first because of the fear that the other side may attack first. In some cases, communication can help overcome this problem, since it can be in both countries’ interests to be known to be rational, but this depends on the specifics of the setting and the type of communication available,as Baliga and Sjöström (2009) show.

3.2 Commitment problems

Commitment problems are probably the single most pervasive reason for bargaining failure. This applies to many aspects of agreements that might avoid conflict, including promises to make future transfers and/or not to attack in the future. The implications of the inability to guarantee an agreement have been understood for centuries and, for instance, underlies the basic anarchic state of nature described by Hobbes (1651) in the Leviathan. As Hobbes states (1651, Chapter 13), "Because of this distrust amongst men, the most reasonable way for any man to make himself safe is to strike first, that is, by force or cunning subdue other men - as many of them as he can, until he sees no other power great enough to endanger him. This is no more than what he
needs for his own survival, and is generally allowed." Effectively there is nothing stopping someone from grabbing resources except fear of retaliation. Hobbes goes on to suggest that reasonable people can come to realize the inherent difficulties with anarchy and cede their rights to a Leviathan in order to live in peace. However, such social contracts do not generally appear in the international arena, and hence for an agreement to endure it has to be balanced in such a way as to be self-enforcing. In some cases, an outside authority, for instance an international organization such as the UN, can serve as an enforcer of an agreement, but the role of that international organization and its members’ incentives to really enforce the agreement are then part of a bigger picture where things need to be self-enforcing. Powell (2006) provides a rich set of illustrations of the pervasiveness of commitment problems.

What does self-enforcement entail? Effectively it must be that, in terms of our earlier discussion, the costs of war subsequent to whatever transfers of wealth or territory become overwhelmingly high. That is, for an agreement to be self-sustaining the states need to be sufficiently balanced in terms of strength and the allocation of resources, so that a war would not benefit any of the states in expectation. It can also be that even if one does not start at such a situation, then by giving up some resources one of the states becomes a less attractive target or a less threatening adversary and one reaches a situation where the costs of war outweigh the potential gains and so peace is self-enforcing. (See Bevia and Corchon (2009) for some discussion). Another way in which things might be made self-enforcing involves reputation. If a country faces potential conflicts with many other countries, then abiding by an agreement with one country can make it possible to credibly abide by agreements in other cases. Thus, it may be in a country's interest to abide by a collection of many agreements even when it might prefer to breach any single one of the agreements in isolation. Such self-enforcement involves embedding in a rich context and will depend on a variety of factors.

Let us also comment on some of the ways that a lack of commitment in agreements might lead to war.

3.2.1 Commitment not to attack after a received transfer or to deliver inter-temporal transfers

The most basic difficulty with a lack of commitment is the obvious one. A country delivering resources cannot trust that the other will not demand more or attack after receiving the resources. A notable example of such a failure of appeasement due to a lack of commitment is the Munich Agreement of 1938, after which Hitler invaded Czechoslovakia despite the agreement.

One idea that has been explored in terms of avoiding such difficulties is to make a series of transfers at a carefully determined rate over time that balances the incentives for conflict against anticipated future transfers. It is not always possible for such an approach to work, but it can in some circumstances, depending on which transfers are possible, how patient the countries are, how imbalanced they are, and how attractive or costly conflict is.

3.2.2 First Strike Advantages and Preemptive War

As the quote of Hobbes makes clear, one difficulty in attaining peace is that the natural anarchy in which international relations reside often leads to a first-strike advantage (preemption). That is, an element of stealth or surprise provides a significant advantage. If there were no first-strike advantage, and countries could have a well- founded expectation of the expected outcome of war, then there would be some mutual allocation of resources leading to a better outcome for all countries than war (presuming that the allocation does not further alter the expected outcome of war). That agreement becomes self-enforcing since it provides countries each with more than their expected resources after a war, and so war is worse for all involved in expectations. However, this presumes that the expected outcome of a war is the same independent of how the war starts. In many cases, the outcome depends on who initiates a war. A significant offensive advantage to war can lead war to be inevitable. As a simple illustration, imagine two evenly matched countries with an even split of resources and a cost to war. If war leads to an evenly matched outcome regardless of who attacks first or under what circumstances, then peace is self-enforcing. In contrast, if a country that strikes first gains a large advantage by doing so, and expects to gain resources with a high enough probability, then peace is destabilized. Each country would like to strike before the other, and also understands that the other also has an incentive to attack first, and so must react by expecting a war, and so war becomes inevitable. Various models of this appear in Powell (1991), Fearon (1995), Chassang and Padro i Miquel (2008), and Morelli and Rohner (2009).

3.2.3 Preventive war

Even in situations where countries are balanced in the short run, a country may fear that an opponent will become stronger over time and that the balance will be destabilized over time,, and may therefore wish to attack today to prevent being attacked by a stronger opponent in the future. Taylor (1954) is an early reference for this perspective, arguing that wars among great powers between 1848 and 1918 can be explained as preventive wars.

Interestingly, preventive incentives are not just an issue when countries are evenly matched and anticipate becoming unevenly matched in the future, but also when one country has a current arms advantage and worries that the other will catch up in the future and that the future situation will be unstable (possibly due to first-strike advantages, or some other considerations), and so wishes to attack while the balance is in their favor. This was an important concern during the early period of the cold war when the United States had nuclear weapon capabilities and the Soviet Union did not. There were debates about whether or not the U.S. should fight a preventative war during both the Truman and Eisenhower administrations. The fact that this did not happen has been argued to be due to a feeling that this was inconsistent with democratic principles (e.g., see the discussion in Silverstone (2007) and Levy (2008)), but from a purely rationalist perspective it might be that the fear of the future instability was insufficient to engage in a war at that time.

3.2.4 War as part of a dynamic bargaining process

Leventoglu and Slantchev (2007) report that almost 70 percent of conflicts end with a negotiated settlement, and almost no conflict ends with the complete elimination of one side, and hence the theory should explain why in many cases a commitment/self- enforcement problem disappears over time and a negotiated settlement eventually becomes feasible. They provide conditions, viewing war as part of a dynamic bargaining process, for a limited war to happen in equilibrium, and commitment to a negotiated settlement to appear after a period of war.

In summary, the pervasiveness of commitment problems comes from the lack of any external enforcement device in an international setting, and so any agreement is really only lasting if it is in the interest of all parties to continue to abide by it. A simple transfer of resources will not suffice unless it aligns incentives, or there are larger reputational concerns involved, or transfers are delicately arranged inter-temporally. There are many factors in such anarchic settings that naturally lead to instability such as preemptive and preventive motives, as well as the earlier mentioned asymmetries of information.

3.3 Indivisibilities and other physical impediments

Consider a situation where a fairly precisely balanced agreement needs to be reached in order to avoid conflict. If it is difficult to finely divide territory, or other natural resources in ways that strike the exact balance needed, that could lead to an inability to reach an agreement in the face of war. While indivisibilities are a seemingly important impediment to bargaining, Fearon (1995) dismisses them as a significant
explanation for war. Even if some resources are indivisible, it must be that there are no other resources that could be used to compensate. Agreements involving trade of large sections of land and money (e.g., the Louisiana Purchase), are plentiful, and the many dimensions through which wealth can be transferred from one state to another make it rare that a war occurs as a result from an inability to divide resources.

In terms of other impediments, delays in communication can make basic forms of bargaining difficult or impossible. While that is less of an issue in modern times, it was a substantial hurdle in times where armies might end up weeks or months in distance away from the leaders that commissioned them (as in the crusades). This leads to substantial delays in communication between the main parties involved in a potential conflict, and in such settings reaching an agreement that avoids conflict may be precluded even if such an agreement exists.

3.4 Agency problems

Even when decision makers are fully informed and have perfectly consistent beliefs, conflict may still be rationally chosen when there are differences in preferences between decision-makers and the rest of their country (a principal-agent problem). As explained in Jackson and Morelli (2007), when the decision-makers are biased relative to their countries war can occur, regardless of the availability of enforceable or binding agreements. The leader of a country might not face the same risks as the country's citizens, or it might be that the leader expects greater gains or glory from a war than the citizens.


Furthermore, as Jackson and Morelli (2007) point out, it can even be that a country would like to choose leaders that have different preferences from that of the country to improve their bargaining position. Overall the risk of war that this implies ex ante can be compensated by the ability of a hawkishly-biased leader to obtain better deals at bargaining tables. This means that even though democracies might be expected to have unbiased leaders who represent the preferences of the average citizen, unbiasedness cannot be guaranteed in democracies either..

Clearly, the ways in which leaders come to power differ across political regimes and this can affect the type of leader that emerges and the extent to which they represent the population as a whole. According to the selectorate theory in Bueno de Mesquita et al. (2003), democratic leaders need a larger coalition to support them relative to non democratic leaders. Keeping a larger coalition satisfied is more costly and hence losing a war is relatively more costly for democratic leaders, and generally makes them less prone to war.

3.5 Multilateral bargaining failures

As an illustration of the potential bargaining failures that arise in a multilateral setting, let us consider a simple three-state conflict. Suppose that there are three equally powerful countries with equal resources. Also suppose that if two countries cooperate, they can easily defeat the third with relatively low costs of war. In such a situation any pair of countries can expect to get almost all of the resources in the world by ganging up on the third. There is no bargain that is stable here.19 If the countries are about to sign an agreement, it must be that at least one of the countries gets at least a third of the total resources. The other two countries could gain by not signing the agreement, cooperating to defeat this third country and then afterwards splitting the resources evenly (and
citizens gain by having a leader whose bargaining position is more hawkish than they would have if they were bargaining on their own behalf.

What happens in settings with multilateral interactions will depend on the specifics of the bargaining process, the relative powers of different coalitions, and many other factors. What is clear, however, is that with three or more countries the fact that there is complete information, divisible outcomes, and an enforceable bargaining technology does not preclude war. This is an important and relatively unexplored territory in the theory of war, and given the innumerable wars that involve more than two states, understanding multilateral bargaining and war is an important area for future research.

Let us add a remark to this. Even when there are just two countries involved in a war, it might be multilateral considerations that derail peace. Although countries are sometimes discussed as if they are unitary actors, it is clear that they are composed of many actors with different objectives. As we know from the basics of collective decision making, an organization that is comprised of many actors does not necessarily act as if it were maximizing some objective function. Basic voting cycles can emerge and so a country composed of individually rational actors can exhibit intransitivities and other inconsistencies in its decision making that make the country difficult or impossible to bargain with.

4. Democratic Peace

As an example of how the various theories interact, let us consider a well-studied empirical regularity in international relations, namely the "democratic peace"; i.e., the observation that democracies rarely go to war with one another (e.g., see Doyle (1986) and Russett (1993)). The idea that incentives of aristocrats to go to war differ from that of democratic leaders is not new, and is well articulated by Kant (1795).
An important explanation of democratic peace is an agency one. As discussed above, Jackson and Morelli (2007) point out, when a leader has a disproportionately high share of benefits relative to costs from war when compared to the average citizen, then war can occur, but such a war will not occur if self-enforcing agreements are feasible and leaders are unbiased representatives. This "unbiased peace" result can be viewed as an explanation of democratic peace, since the checks and balances of a democracy can help reduce the chance of having a biased leader.
Conconi et al. (2009) extend this argument from Jackson and Morelli (2007), introducing an explicit election and reelection mechanism to control the bias of leaders. They show, theoretically and empirically, that the incentives of reelection can lead leaders to be unbiased in their decision-making, but that democratically elected leaders who do not face re-election can act similarly to autocratic leaders. Thus, the democratic peace observations are refined, and it is democratically elected leaders who face reelection who do not go to war with other democratically elected leaders also facing reelection. But autocrats or democratically elected leaders under the last term of a term- limit can diverge from the population’s interests and go to war. So it seems that a driving force behind the democratic peace is how a leader's incentives are kept in line with the population through potential reelection.

It is worth noting that the interactions between an executive’s behavior and election prospects can be quite complicated. For example, going counter to the incentives to avoid conflict when facing reelection, there are also ``wag the dog’’ sorts of situations, such as that described by Hess and Orphanides (1995, 2001), where an incumbent leader facing poor reelection prospects has greater incentives to initiate a war. The Hess and Orphanides (1995) explanation is that a conflict might reveal information about the leader’s abilities to the electorate that increases the probability of reelection. As Hess and Orphanides (2001b) suggest, such behavior can be correlated with recessions where an incumbent may be at a disadvantage.

Moving to the role of asymmetric information for the explanation of democratic peace, Fearon (1997) emphasized that so called "audience costs" (the cost of misrepresentations) are much higher in a democracy, and substantial audience costs can make signaling of information more effective in democracies, which in turn reduces asymmetries in information, and thus reduces the probability of war.
Fearon (2008) emphasizes another channel to rationalize democratic peace that involves commitment issues. The stronger country between two potential contenders usually has a higher GDP per capita. If it is democratic, then, even if the leader promises to a set of supporters some benefits from the war, it cannot avoid the possibility that eventually, once democratic rules apply to the unified country in case of victory, the GDP per capita of the winning country will go down. Hence voters of a richer democracy who believe that the unified country will lead to wealth redistribution should be against the war, and hence only weak contenders should remain interested in wars. However, weaker countries will generally have less interest in entering a conflict to begin with due to a low probability of success.

5. Endogenous Power

So far we have not talked much about the incentives of countries to arm. It is important to recognize that the probability of war depends on prior investments in arms, and that in turn the incentives to arm depend on how arms affect future incentives to go to war or to bargain. Thus, to fully understand decisions to go to war, such decisions cannot be divorced from the broader endogenous armament environment in which they reside.

There are studies of armament decisions in the case where conflict is inevitable (or bargaining is inevitable), such as that of Hirshleifer (1989, 1995) and Skaperdas (1992). The case were both decisions, whether to arm and whether to attack, are present
is analyzed in Powell (1993) and Jackson and Morelli (2009). The key difference in the analyses is the timing of the arming decisions. Powell's model leads to peace, and is one where countries move in alternating time periods and have their armament levels fixed for the intermediate periods. In such a setting, country 1 will set its arms at a level that it knows will be sufficient to deter the other country. The other country when called upon to move must then set its arms at a similar level, to deter future attacks when the first country can readjust its arms. This results in constant positive armaments and perpetual peace. In Jackson and Morelli (2009), the armament decisions are simultaneous, so that there is a sense in which countries cannot fully react to each other's armament levels but must anticipate them. In that setting, for a range of scenarios, countries randomize22 between a variety of strategies that must include hawkish, dovish, and deterrence armament levels. Of course, this is in the absence of commitment, as otherwise countries would sign binding agreements not to attack each other and the question of armament would become moot. The intuition behind why war is inevitable and some variation in arms levels necessarily result is fairly straightforward. A complete lack of arms on the part of both countries is not a stable outcome, since a country that anticipates that the other will be completely unprotected, would prefer to arm and attack (presuming that the costs of war are not overwhelmingly high, in which case perpetual peace and no arms are an equilibrium). Let us then consider the other extreme, where both countries arm to a high level, and mutually deter attacks. This also fails to be an equilibrium point. Given that there is a positive cost of war, it is true that if the countries are both heavily armed, then neither wants to attack the other. However, given the costs of war, deterrence is still assured if one country slightly reduces its arms. Given the savings of arms costs, then it cannot be an equilibrium for mutually high levels, as one country should lower its arms level to a slightly lower deterrence level. This incentive then ends up ratcheting down the arms levels, as it is always better to have slightly lower arms than the other country given that war will not occur if arms levels are close enough to each other. However, if we keep
ratcheting arms levels down so that the countries are not arming very much, then we return to the first reasoning that one of the countries should deviate to arm heavily and go to war. So, there is no stable pair of arms levels, and the equilibrium must involve some randomization, and over at least several types of arms levels. Jackson and Morelli also investigate comparative statics when there is a probability that the countries will have an opportunity to bargain (in a credible way) to avoid a war. Increasing the probability of a bargaining opportunity leads countries to make less use of deterrence armament strategies and more use of hawkish and dovish strategies, so the possibility of potential conflict increases. The idea is that as bargaining becomes more likely, deterrence strategies become less valuable, all else held equal, as do hawkisk strategies, while dovish strategies become more valuable. To ensure stability, one needs to increase the use of dovish strategies, which then reestablishes value to the hawkish strategies and increases their use, which then also maintains a reason to have at least some deterrence activity. The overall comparative statics that come out of this are that there is a lower probability of war due to the increased bargaining opportunities; however, there is a higher probability of war conditional on bargaining not being feasible.
Interestingly, peaceful outcomes are not necessarily the efficient ones in such endogenous-arms settings. Arms are wasteful, and so having many periods of peace but with costly armament levels can be worse than simply having an early conflict and then thereafter living in a unified country with peace without the need for arms.23
Another interesting case is the one in which arms remain unobservable even after the investment phase has ended and war is about to start. Meirowitz and Sartori (2008) analyze this case, and they also show that war cannot be avoided even if bargaining technologies exist. In their case, the source of the positive probability of war is asymmetric information, whereas in Jackson and Morelli's observable case the bargaining failures fall under the category of commitment and enforcement frictions.

Beyond these models of endogenous power, there are also models such as that of Chassang and Padro i Miquel (2008). They do comparative statics in weapons stocks which sheds light on the incentives to arm and which sorts of arms and levels of arms countries might seek. They note that the advantage to a first strike affects the perceived value to the attacker, while the incentive to preemptively attack rather than risk being attacked is something that comes out of the payoffs of the potential target. Increasing the arms of just one country increases the advantage over an opponent in terms of a striking first which can increase preemption tensions. However, mutual increases in arms can lower the risk of suffering an attack and lower preemption tensions. They use this to note that extremely destructive weapons such as nuclear weapons can produce a more even balance and result in mutual deterrence, while arming with less destructive weapons might provide enough of an asymmetry that it results in incentives to strike first, and thus also an incentive to preemptively attack.

6. The duration of wars

As mentioned briefly in the introduction, part of the importance of understanding the various reasons for war is that different scenarios lead to different sorts of outcomes. To see this most starkly, consider a situation where a war starts due to a lack of commitment. In such a case a war can be protracted. A peace agreement only becomes attainable after the balance of power has shifted so that it becomes in both sides’ interest to agree to peace. This can take a long time. In contrast, if bargaining is possible, but fails due to asymmetric information about the relative strengths of countries, then a bargain should be reached as soon as the relative strengths of the countries becomes clear. This may take some time, but might happen much more quickly, and with lower costs, than it would take for the balance of power to shift significantly enough to lead to self-enforcement.

Exactly how long the war might last when there is no ability to commit can depend on many factors. In the case of asymmetric information, a model that offers predictions in this regard, where a country learns about another country's strength or resolve over time, is often referred to as a war of attrition (e.g., see Smith (1974) and Bishop and Cannings (1978)). The time at which a war of attrition ends depends on the specifics of the gain from winning, the costs of staying in the conflict, the patience of
the actors, and the level of uncertainty. The basic structure is one where two opponents incur costs at some rate per unit of time as long as they stay in conflict. The first one to give up loses and the other one wins. The uncertainty can be about the value to the other from winning, or the cost of conflict, or the patience. As the conflict goes on, it reveals that the other has not yet given up indicating a higher patience, lower cost, or greater patience. Eventually one of the two sides gives up.
It should be clear that our discussion applies to many sorts of conflicts and not just to inter-state wars. For example it applies to things like civil wars, coups and revolutions, and even strikes and other social and economic conflicts. Indeed, even some of the literature that is specifically aimed at understanding conflict in one arena can shed light on others. As an example, Acemoglu, Ticchi and Vindigni (2009) provide an explanation for the long duration of some civil wars. They explain that a government can fear having too strong a military, as a strong military can initiate coups especially in contexts where a government cannot commit to maintaining the resources directed to the military once a conflict ends. Understanding this interaction between a government and a military thus provides an additional lens into arming decisions, which then not only affects the number of conflicts that take place internally and their duration (as for instance a weaker military may take a long time to eradicate a rebel group), but then also has implications for the likelihood and potential duration of external conflicts.

7. Concluding remarks

We have presented a rich framework within which we can understand the prerequisites for war. Although our discussion has drawn mainly from the large literature on inter-state war, many of the same issues are at play in civil wars and other forms of conflict. Again, there must exist incentives for conflict and some barriers to the ability to reach an enforceable bargain. Some revolutions and coups arise from an agency problem either on the part of the current ruler or the leader of the attack. Some civil wars erupt because of ethnic or religious diversities manifesting themselves in the form of multilateral bargaining failures.
Although the theoretical understanding of the various causes of wars is developing well, and there are innumerable case studies of war and analyses of particular conflicts, systematic empirical work that analyzes the origins of wars across many cases is still relatively lacking. A richer understanding of the origins of wars would help further advance the theory, and would help in sorting more frequent and important causes from those which are less so; and ultimately would help in developing policies aimed at avoiding the costs of conflict.
Bibliography
Abreu, Dilip (1988): "Towards a Theory of Discounted Repeated Games," Econometrica, Vol. 56(2), 383-96.
Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, J.A. Robinson (2001) "The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation," The American Economic Review, Vol. 91, No. 5, pp. 1369-1401.
Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, J.A. Robinson (2005) "Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth," Chapter 6 in The Handbook of Economic Growth 1A, edited by P. Aghion and S. Durlauf, Elsevier.
Acemoglu, D., D. Ticchi, and A. Vindigni (2009) ``Persistence of Civil Wars,’’ mimeo: MIT
Alesina, A. and E. Spolaore (1997) "On the Number and Size of Nations," Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112 No. 4, 1027-1056.
Aumann, R.J. (1976) "Agreeing to Disagree," The Annals of Statistics, Vol. 4, No. 6 (Nov., 1976), pp. 1236-1239
Baliga, Sandeep and Tomas Sjöström (2004): "Arms Races and Negotiations," Review of Economic Studies, 71(2), 351-69.
Baliga, S. and T. Sjöström (2009) "The Strategy of Manipulating Conflict,"
27
Bevia, C. and L. Corchon (2009) "Peace Agreements without commitment ," mimeo: Universitat Autonoma de Barcelona.
Bishop, D.T. and Cannings, C. (1978) A generalized war of attrition. Journal of Theoretical Biology 70: 85-124
Blainey, Geoffrey. (1973): The Causes of War, New York: the Free Press.
Bloch, F., S. Sanchez-Pages, and R. Soubeyran (2006) "When does Universal Peace Prevail? Secession and Group Formation in Conflict," Economics of Governance, Vol. 7, 3-29.
Brito, D.L. and M.D. Intriligator (1985) `` Conflict, War, and Redistribution, ‘’ The American Political Science Review, Vol. 79, No. 4, 943-957.
Bueno de Mesquita, B. (1981): The War Trap, Yale University Press. Bueno de Mesquita, B., J.D. Morrow, R.M. Siverson and A. Smith (2003): Logic of
Political survival, MIT Press.
Bueno de Mesquita, E.A. (1999): "An Institutional Explanation of the Democratic Peace"
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce., and Randolph M. Siverson (1995): "War and the Survival of Political Leaders: A Comparative Study of Regime Types and Political Accountability," American Political Science Review, 89(4), 841-55.
Cai, H. (2003) "War or Peace." in Contributions to Economic Analysis and Policy, BE Press, Vol 2, No 1, Article 2.
Chassang, S. and G. Padró i Miquel (2008) "Conflict and Deterrence under Strategic Risk," NBER Working Paper # 13964.
Chassang, S. and G. Padró i Miquel (2008b) "Mutual Fears and Civil War," BREAD Working Paper # 165.
Chassang, S. and G. Padró i Miquel (2009) "Economic Shocks and Civil War," forthcoming: Quarterly Journal of Political Science.
Chiozza, Giacomo and Hein E. Goemans (2004): "International Conflict and the Tenure of Leaders: Is War Still Ex Post Costly?" American Journal of Political Science, 48(3), 604-19.
Clausewitz, Carl von (1832)[1976]: On War, edited and translated by Michael Howard and Peter Paret, Princeton University Press.
28
Conconi, P., N. Sahuguet, and M. Zanardi (2009) "Democratic Peace and Electoral Accountability," mimeo: ECARES and CEPR.
Crawford, V. (1982), ``A Theory of Disagreement in Bargaining,’’ Econometrica 50,607- 637.
Downs, George W. and David M. Rocke (1994): "Conflict, Agency, and Gambling for Resurrection: The Principal-Agent Problem Goes to War," American Journal of Political Science, 38(2), 362-80.
Ellingsen, T., and T. Miettinen (2008), "Commitment and Conflict in Bilateral Bargaining", American Economic Review 98, 1629-1635.
Esteban, J. and D. Ray (2008) "On the Salience of Ethnic Conflict," American Economic Review, 98, 2185-2202.
Fearon, J.D. (1995) "Rationalist explanations for war," International Organization, 49:3, 379-414.
Fearon, J.D. (1996) "Bargaining over Objects that Influence Future Bargaining Power," mimeo.
Fearon, J.D. (1997): "Signaling Foreign Policy Interests: Tying Hands versus Sinking Costs," Journal of Conflict Resolution, 41(1), 68-90.
Fearon, J.D. (2008) ``A Simple Political Economy of Relations among Democracies and Autocracies,’’ mimeo: Stanford University.
Fisher, Markus (1992) Feudal Europe, 800–1300: Communal Discourse and Conflictual Practices. International Organization 46:427-66.
Garfinkel, M. (1990): "Arming as a Strategic Investment in a Cooperative Equilibrium," American Economic Review, Vol. 80-4, 50-68.
Garfinkel, Michelle R. and Stergios Skaperdas (2000): "Conflict without Misperceptions or Incomplete information: how the Future Matters," Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 44-6, 793-807.
Gartzke, E.A. (1999): "War Is in the Error Term," International Organization, 53(3), 567-87.
Gutmann, Myron P. (1988): "The Origins of the Thirty Years' War," Journal of Interdisciplinary History, Vol. 18, No. 4, The Origin and Prevention of Major Wars (Spring), pp. 749-770 Published by: The MIT Press
29
Hess, G. and A. Orphanides (1995) ``War Politics: An Economic rational-voter framework’’ in the American Economic Review, 85: 4, 828-846.
Hess, G. and A. Orphanides (2001) ``War and Democracy,’’ Journal of Political Economy, 2001, vol. 109, no. 4, 776-810.
Hess, G. and A. Orphanides (2001b) ``Economic Conditions, Elections, and the Magnitude of Foreign Conflicts,’’ Journal of Public Economics, 80:1, 121-140.
Hirshleifer, Jack (1989): "Conflict and rent-seeking success functions: Ratio vs. difference models of relative success, " Public Choice, Public Choice 63: 101-112.
Hirshleifer, J. (1995) "Anarchy and its Breakdown," The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 103, No. 1, 26-52.
Hobbes, T. (1651) Leviathan, or the Matter, Forme, and Power of a Commonwealth, Ecclesiasticall and Civil,
http://www.earlymoderntexts.com/f_hobbes.html [Focus on Chapters 13, 14, 15, 17-24, 26, 29, (they are short)]
Intriligator, Michael D. (1964) "Some Simple Models of Arms Races," Rand Report Intriligator, Michael D. (1975) "Strategic Considerations in the Richardson Model of
Arms Races," The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 83, No. 2, 339-354 Intriligator, Michael D. (1982) "Research on Conflict Theory: Analytic Approaches and
Areas of Application ," The Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 26, No. 2. Jackson, M.O. and M. Morelli (2007) "Political Bias and War," American Economic
Review, 97:4, 1353-1373. Jackson, M.O. and M. Morelli (2008) "Strategic Militarization, Deterrence and War
between Nations," http://www.stanford.edu/~jacksonm/gunsbutter.pdf
Jervis, Robert (1976): Perception and Misperception in International Politics, Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Jervis, Robert (1978): "Cooperation under the Security Dilemma," World Politics, 30(2), 167-214.
Jones, S. (1989), "Have your Lawyer Call my Lawyer: Bilateral Delegation in Bargaining Situations", Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 11, 159-174.
30
Jones, D.M., S.A. Bremer, and J.D. Singer (1996) "Militarized Interstate Disputes, 1816- 1992: Rationale, Coding Rules, and Empirical Patterns," Conflict Management and Peace Science, VOL. 15, NO. 2, 163-215.
Jordan, James, (2006): "Pillage and Property", Journal of Economic Theory, Volume 131, Issue 1 , November, Pages 26-44.
Kaiser, D. (1990): Politics and War: European Conflict from Philip II to Hitler Kant, I. [1795] (1991) "Toward Perpetual Peace: A Philosophical Sketch," in Reiss,
Kant's Political Writings, Cambridge University Press, pp. 93-130. Kaplan, M.A. (1957) System and Process in International Relations, New York: Wiley.
Kirshner, Jonathan (2000): "Rationalist Explanations for War?" Security Studies, 10(1), 143-50.
Kocherlakota, N.R. (1996) "Implications of Efficient Risk Sharing without Commitment," The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 63, No. 4., pp. 595-609.
Krasner, Stephen D. (1995): "Compromising Westphalia," International Security, Vol. 20, No. 3 pp. 115-51.
Kydd, Andrew H. (1997). "Game Theory and the Spiral Model," World Politics Vol. 49(3), 371-400.
Kydd, Andrew (2000) "Arms races and arms control: Modeling the hawk perspective," American Journal of Political Science, 44 (2), 228—244.
Lake, David A. (1992): "Powerful Pacifists: Democratic States and War," American Political Science Review, 86(1), 24-37.
LeBreton, M. and S. Weber (2003) "The Art of Making Everybody Happy: How to Prevent a Secession," IMF Staff Papers, Vol 50, No. 3, 403-435.
Leventoglu, Bahar, and Branislav Slantchev (2007): "The Armed Peace: A Punctuated Equilibrium Theory of War", American Journal of Political Science, vol. 51 no. ...
Levy, Jack (2008) "Preventive War and Democratic Politics" in International Studies Quarterly 52:1.
Luard, Evan (1986): War in International Society, Yale University Press.
Madarasz, K. (2009) "Bargaining and Conflict with Biased Beliefs," mimeo: Budapest University of Economic Sciences.
31
32 Mansfield, E.D., and J. Snyder (1995): "Democratization and the Danger of War,"
International Security Vol. 20 no.1, 5-39. McBride, M. and S. Skaperdas (2009) "Conflict, Settlement, and the Shadow of the
Future," mimeo: University of California, Irvine.
Meirowitz, A.H. and K. Ramsay (2009) "Institutions, Investing, and Fighting: A game- free result about the odds of war," mimeo: Princeton University.
Meirowitz, A.H. and A.E. Sartori (2007) "Secrecy and War: The Origins of Private Information", Quarterly Journal of Political Science.
Midlarsky, M.I. (): Handbook of War Studies, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Morelli, M. and D. Rohner (2009) ``Natural Resource Distribution and. Multiple Forms
of Civil War.,’’ mimeo: Columbia University. Mueller, J. (1990) Retreat from Doomsday: The Obsolescence of Major War, Basic
Books. Myerson, R.B., and M.A. Satterthwaite (1981) "Efficient Mechanisms for Bilateral
Trading," Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 29. No. 2. Niou, Emerson M.S., Peter C. Ordeshook, and Gregory F. Rose (1989): The Balance of
Power; Stability in International Systems. Cambridge University Press. O’Neill, Barry (1990) ``A Survey of Game Theory Models on Peace and War,’’
Handbook of Game Theory, ed. By R. Aumann and S. Hart, Elsevier: NY. Piccione, Michele and Ariel Rubinstein (2007) "Equilibrium in the Jungle," The
Economic Journal, Vol 117-522, 883-96. Powell, R. (1993) "Guns, Butter and Anarchy," American Political Science Review, 87,
115-132;
Powell, R. (1999) In the Shadow of Power. Princeton: Princeton University Press;
Powell, R. (2004) "The inefficient use of power: Costly conflict with complete information," American Political Science Review 98(2), 231-242.
Powell, R. (2006) "War as a Commitment Problem," International Organization, 60, 169– 203.
Querou, N. (2009) ``Commitment and the optimality of negotiation or conflict,’’ mimeo. Querou, N. (2009b) ``Group bargaining and conflict,’’ mimeo.
Powell, R. (2009) ``Persistent Fighting to Forestall Adverse Shifts in the Distribution of Power,’’ mimeo: UC Berkeley.
Ray, D. (2007) A Game-Theoretic Perspective on Coalition Formation, Oxford University Press: U.K..
Ray, D. (2009) "Costly Conflict under Complete Information," mimeo: NYU. Richardson (1960) Arms and Insecurity, Boxwood.
Runciman, Sir Stephen (1951-1954) A History of the Crusades, 3 vols., Cambridge Press. democratic peace:
Russett, B. (1993) Grasping the Democratic Peace: Principles for a Post-Cold War World, Princeton University Press: Princeton N.J.
Russett, Bruce, Christopher Layne, David E. Spiro, Michael W. Doyle (1995), Correspondence section of International Security, 19(4), 164-84.
Sanchez-Pages, S. (2005): "Conflict as a Part of the Bargaining Process," Economic Journal, forthcoming.
Schelling, Thomas C. (1963): The Strategy of Conflict, London and New York, Oxford University Press.
Schelling, Thomas C. (1966): Arms and Influence, New Haven and London, Yale University Press.
Schultz, K. (1998) "Domestic opposition and signaling in international crises," American Political Science Review 92 (4), 829—844.
Schwarz, M. and K. Sonin (2008) ``A Theory of Brinkmanship, Conflicts, and Commitments,’’ Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization. 24(1): 161-183.
Silverstone, Scott A. 2007. Preventive War and American Democracy, New York: Routledge.
Slantchev, B. (2003) "The power to hurt: Costly conflict with completely informed states," American Political Science Review 97 (1), 123—133.
Slantchev, B. (2005) "Military coercion in interstate crises," American Political Science Review, 99 (4), 533-547.
Slantchev, B. (2007) ``Feigning Weakness,’’ mimeo: University of California at San Diego.
33
34 Skaperdas S. (1992) "Cooperation, Conflict, and Power in the Absence of Property
Rights," The American Economic Review, Vol. 82, No. 4, 720-739.
Smith, A. (1998): "Fighting Battles, Winning Wars; Opening up the Black Box of War: Politics and the Conduct of War." The Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 42, No. 3, 301-20.
Smith, A. and A. Stam (2003) ``Bargaining and the Nature of War,’’ Journal of Conflict Resolution, 20:10, 1-30.
Smith, J.M. (1974) Theory of games and the evolution of animal contests. Journal of Theoretical Biology 47: 209-221.
Tarar, Ahmer (2006): "Diversionary Incentives and the Bargaining Approach to War," International Studies Quarterly, Vol. 50-1.
Taylor, A.J.P. (1954): The Struggle for Mastery in Europe, 1848 to 1918, Oxford, Clarendon Press.
Ticchi, D. and A. Vindigni (2009) "War and Endogenous Democracy," mimeo: Princeton University.
Wagner, R.H. (1986): "The Theory of Games and the Balance of Power," World Politics, 38(4), 546-576.
Wagner, R. H. (2000) "Bargaining and War," American Journal of Political Science, 44(3), 469-84.

Waltz, K. (1959): Man, the State, and War, Columbia University Press: N.Y.